Next Article in Journal
Do Financial Professionals Process Information Better as a Group Than Non-Professionals?
Next Article in Special Issue
Tax Rates and Tax Revenues in the Context of Tax Competitiveness
Previous Article in Journal
Risk Management: Exploring Emerging Human Resource Issues during the COVID-19 Pandemic
Previous Article in Special Issue
Empirical Estimation of Intraday Yield Curves on the Italian Interbank Credit Market e-MID
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Financial Contagion: A Tale of Three Bubbles

by
Nathan Burks
1,
Adetokunbo Fadahunsi
2 and
Ann Marie Hibbert
3,*
1
Department of Finance, West Virginia University, Morgantown, WV 26506, USA
2
Department of Statistics, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA 22030, USA
3
Department of Finance, John Chambers College of Business and Economics, West Virginia University, Morgantown, WV 26505, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14(5), 229; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14050229
Submission received: 27 March 2021 / Revised: 13 May 2021 / Accepted: 14 May 2021 / Published: 20 May 2021
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Economic Forecasting)

Abstract

:
The primary purpose of the study is to identify and measure the properties of asset bubbles, volatility clustering, and financial contagion during three recent financial market anomalies that originated in the U.S. and Chinese markets. In particular, we focus on the 2000 DotCom Bubble, the 2008 Housing Crisis, and the 2015 Chinese Bubble. We employ three main empirical methods; the LPPL model to identify asset bubbles, the DCC-GARCH model to measure volatility clustering, and the Diebold-Yilmaz volatility spillover index to measure the level of financial contagion. We provide robust evidence that during the DotCom bubble there was very limited spillover between the S&P 500, the Shanghai, and the Shenzhen Composite Indexes. However, there was significantly more spillover effects in the two more recent crises, i.e., the Housing crisis and the 2015 Chinese Bubble. Together, these results highlight the fact that as financial markets have become more globalized, there are greater levels of volatility transmission and correspondingly fewer potential benefits from international diversification.

1. Introduction

Asset bubbles, volatility clustering, and financial contagion have long been of interest to researchers, market participants, and regulators. Prior research has largely focused on each of these phenomena separately, with little focus on examining them within a unified framework. Our main goal in this paper is to fill the void in the literature by investigating the dynamic correlation and contagion between notable economic bubbles in two major economies, i.e., the U.S. and Chinese stock markets. The increase in globalization led to markets being more interconnected. In our first two research questions, we investigate whether there was an increase in the level of volatility persistence and spillover during three recent major bubbles: the Dot-Com Bubble of 1995–2001, the Housing Bubble of 2008, and the Chinese equity bubble of 2014–2015. Since prior literature confirms that an additional source of risk in financial markets is the degree of variability in volatility (see for example Agarwal et al. 2017), with our third research question, we investigate whether there was an increase in the volatility of volatility (hereafter vol of vol) in each of these markets, during each bubble.
Using daily data on the S&P 500 Index, the SSE Composite Index (Shanghai), and the SZSE Composite Index (Shenzhen), we make at least four important contributions to the literature. First, we show that the U.S. and Chinese stock markets have had an evolving relationship during times of financial turbulence, but the volatility clustering effect between the two markets has been consistently elevated. Second, we provide empirical evidence on the evolution of the vol of vol of each market during each of the bubbles. Our results confirm that the Chinese indexes exhibit high vol of vol during the Dot-Com Bubble, but the S&P 500 maintained relatively low vol of vol in that period. In the case of the Housing Bubble, both U.S. and Chinese equity markets experienced low vol of vol, while in the more recent Chinese Bubble, the Chinese indexes exhibit little vol of vol, while the S&P 500 had elevated vol of vol. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to investigate the vol of vol in each of these markets during each of these financial crises. These results are important for market participants who are concerned with hedging the risk of increased volatility.
In our third contribution, we show that the initiation and conclusion (popping) of asset bubbles can be empirically simulated through the volatility clustering process. Our results suggest that the Log Periodic Power Law (LPPL) model of Bree and Joseph (2013) is capable of accurately identifying a bubble period. Fourth, using the model of Diebold and Yilmaz (2009, 2012), we quantify the level of spillover between each market during each of these crises. Our results reveal that the S&P 500 is having a lower spillover effect to the Chinese markets, while Shenzhen’s effect is gradually increasing, especially in the post-Housing Bubble period. Our results on the spillover effect from the U.S. market is consistent with the finding of Bekaert et al. (2014), who also document only weak evidence of transmission from U.S. equity markets to other countries during the Housing Bubble. However, our finding on the increasing spillover effect from the Shenzhen market is novel and highlights the important shifts in volatility transmission during this most recent financial crisis.

2. Related Literature and Hypotheses Development

Previous research into what features constitute a “bubble” is highly subjective and often conflicting.1 Historically, financial bubbles are generated when the market value of an index or asset class far exceeds the actual intrinsic value. Per Case and Shiller (2003), a bubble is a market situation where irrational investor expectations of future price increases cause current prices to be unjustifiably elevated. However, in analyzing any (supposed) bubble, it is important to consider the impact of governmental and economic policy on equity markets. For example, a shift in policy can also shift the benchmark for a market anomaly to be correctly designated as an asset bubble. This phenomenon is referred to as “process switching” (Flood and Hodrick 1986), which presents investors a more nuanced perspective of fundamental economic conditions.2

2.1. The Dot-Com Bubble

According to Robert Shiller (2000), various bubbles are largely due to a populist assumption of supposed “new eras” in an economy. New eras are investor beliefs that markets have been permanently altered by some underlying factor or trend, even though the structure of these markets have not changed. An Internet mania saw the Nasdaq Composite Index increasing by almost 400% over the 5-years from 1995 to 2000. In fact, “in the two-year period from early 1998 through February 2000, the Internet sector earned over 1000 percent returns on its public equity” (Ofek and Richardson 2003). However, once this bubble burst, the Nasdaq lost 78% of its value.

2.2. The Housing Bubble

The Housing Bubble, which ultimately led to the global financial crisis of 2008, had a more prolonged, detrimental effect on the U.S. macro economy. The new era that the Housing Bubble embodied was far more unprecedented. Rather than asset values being simply skewed away from intrinsic values, there was a major systemic breakdown in the U.S. banking and financial system. Not only were home values and mortgages wildly inflated, but massive subprime lending, combined with increased securitization, led to global economic calamity. According to the S&P/Case-Shiller national home-price index, home prices in the U.S. rose 124% over a 9-year span from 1997 to 2006. Lending institutions took advantage of these astronomical price increases by implementing what some consider reckless practices involving unreasonable leveraging and subprime CDOs. When this bubble burst, the S&P 500 lost approximately 50% of its value. Although the root cause of the Dot-Com and Housing Bubbles are quite different, the global impact from the deconstruction of both market events was similar in their scope. A large number of studies have investigated contagion during this period (see for example, Wang et al. 2017; Jin and An 2016; Dimitriou et al. 2013).

2.3. The 2015 Chinese Bubble

The U.S. and Chinese economies have become more integrated over recent history (Johansson 2010). A major theoretical reason for possible co-movements in Chinese and U.S. equity markets relates to the Chinese legislation of the Qualified Foreign Institutional Investor (QFII) and Qualified Domestic Institutional Investor (QDII) programs. The QFII was passed in 2002 and allowed certain international investors access to A-shares in the Shanghai and Shenzhen stock exchanges, while the QDII was passed in 2008 and allowed Chinese investors to invest in U.S. equity indexes. Accordingly, a bilateral exchange was created for U.S. and Chinese financial trading. However, with the liberalization of markets in a communist regime, a more laissez faire approach is introduced and the existing relation between macroeconomic data and variables may be drastically altered (Lucas 1976). This shift in control would eventually play an integral role in the 2015 Chinese market bubble.
Between June 2014 and June 2015, the Shanghai index appreciated by approximately 150%, while the Shenzhen index increased by about 190%. A primary reason for this sudden bubble within these Chinese stock indexes was the implementation of margin trading in Chinese equities (Song 2020). With this new infusion of debt and leverage in the Chinese stock markets, the Shanghai and Shenzhen exchanges were propped up in value. When this bubble burst, the results were more devastating than could be imagined, $2.6 trillion of the Shanghai and Shenzhen indexes was eroded (Zeng et al. 2016). During this period, market volatility skyrocketed and stock indexes across the globe plummeted.

2.4. Financial Contagion and Volatility Persistence

Forbes and Rigobon (2002) define contagion as a significant increase in cross-market dynamic correlations over a certain period, in contrast to interdependence, defined as when markets have a strong dynamic correlation consistently over time. Bekaert et al. (2014) investigate transmission of the crisis from the U.S. to the equity markets of 415 countries during the Housing Bubble and find only weak evidence for international contagion from U.S. equity markets. In contrast, Chiang and Wang (2011) find evidence of volatility of volatility transmission from the U.S. to some G7 countries during the housing crisis. BenMim and BenSaïda (2019) also report significant contagion between the U.S. and countries in the Eurozone during crises periods. Similarly, Gomez-Gonzalez et al. (2018) document transmission of the housing bubble from the U.S. mostly to European countries.
Whereas most of the extant literature focus on a single bubble period, we consider multiple bubble periods. Furthermore, while most of the prior studies focus on bubbles that originate in the U.S. or European stock markets, we extend the literature by investigating a bubble that originated in the Chinese economy. The S&P 500 index experienced a marked increase in volatility immediately preceding the crash of the Housing Bubble, while the Shanghai and Shenzhen indexes had marked decreases in volatility during the same period (Sornette et al. 2018). However, even with these fluctuations in historical volatility, the volatility persistence could still maintain an elevated level. For example, the dynamic nature of contagion can cause an increase in the autocorrelation of market volatility with large price changes following large price changes and small price changes following small price changes. These patterns in price fluctuations cause a cluster effect, with the interlinked, forecastable volatility present in the markets, otherwise known as volatility clustering (Mandelbrot 1963).
We examine the recent Chinese market turmoil, as well as the Dot-Com and Housing Bubbles, to establish whether there is contagion of volatility cluster over the course of Chinese market liberalization. The study that is most closely related to ours is that of Imran Yousaf et al. (2020) who investigate return and volatility transmission from the U.S. and Chinese markets to countries in Latin America during the housing bubble and the Chinese crises. However, they do not investigate transmission between the U.S. and Chinese markets. They also acknowledge the need to reexamine these market linkages using other econometric models, as we do in this study. Unlike their study and others that investigate economic bubbles, financial contagion, and volatility clustering independently, our study provides a combined view of the evolving relation between these three elements.

3. Data and Empirical Methods

3.1. Data and Descriptive Statistics

We collect daily levels of the S&P 500 Index, the SSE Composite Index (Shanghai), and the SZSE Composite Index (Shenzhen) from Bloomberg. We use the period from 4 January 1995 to 30 November 2004 for the Dot-Com Bubble; from 1 December 2004 to 16 March 2009 for the Housing Bubble; and from 5 May 2014 to 15 September 2015 for the 2015 Chinese Bubble.3 The starting and ending points for the Dot-Com and Housing Bubble samples are based on Bekaert et al. (2014) and Lin et al. (2014). We estimate the period of the 2015 Chinese Bubble by fitting the volatility-confined LPPL model to the data. We provide details of the model in Section 3.2.

3.2. Log Periodic Power Law (LPPL) Model

We use the Log Periodic Power Law (LPPL) model of Bree and Joseph (2013) to empirically test for the constitution of an asset bubble. The model is given as:
log   ( y t ) = A + B   ( t   c t )   m   { 1 + C   c o s   ( ω   l o g   ( t c t ) + φ ) }
where log(yt) > 0 is the log of the index at time t, A > 0 is the value that log yt would have if the bubble were to last until the critical time tc, B < 0 is the decrease in yt over the time unit before the crash if C is close to zero, C is the magnitude of the fluctuations around the exponential growth, as a proportion, tc > 0 is the critical time, t < tc is any time into the bubble, preceding tc, m is the exponent of the power law growth, ω is the frequency of the fluctuations during the bubble, and φ is a shift parameter.
The parameters of the LPPL econophysics approach have been widely employed as theoretical indicators of speculative market bubbles and as precursors to subsequently ensuing market crashes (Zhang et al. 2016). In theory, if a stock index conforms to the price power law acceleration and log periodic oscillations as stipulated by the LPPL model, a market crash would be considered as very likely (Bree and Joseph 2013). In this study we use a variant of the LPPL model, i.e., the volatility-confined LPPL model (Lin et al. 2014) which is parameterized by the price dynamics:
d I I = μ ( t ) d t + σ Y   d Y + σ W d W κ d j
d Y = α Y   d t + d W
The notation I delineates the stock index and W represents a standard Weiner process. Time-varying drift leading to price acceleration in a bubble regime, represented by µ(t), is accompanied by a jump process, denoted by j, which has a value of zero before a bubble crash and a value of one following a bubble crash. For the values 0 < α < 1, Y is indicative of an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck or mean-reverting process, where the variables dY and Y are stationary. Therefore, the parameters of a volatility-confined bubble are indicative of a bubble regime within the context of GARCH processes.
Appendix A provides details of the calibration of the LPPL model for the 2015 Chinese bubble.

3.3. DCC-GARCH Model

The multivariate DCC-GARCH model (Engle 2002) can be expressed as follows:
r t = μ t + ε t
where rt is log return of the index at time t, μt is expected return of the index and εt, the error term is independent and identically distributed with mean 0 and variance of 1. The conditional variance-covariance matrix is written as:
H t = D t R t D t
where Rt is the time-varying correlation matrix and Dt is a diagonal matrix of conditional standard deviations for return series. The conditional correlation matrix is written as:
R t = ( d i a g ( Q t ) ) 1 / 2 Q t ( d i a g ( Q t ) ) 1 / 2
where ( d i a g ( Q t ) ) 1 / 2 = d i a g ( 1 q 11 , t 1 q n n , t )
The evolution of the correlation in the DCC model is given by:
Q t = ( 1 α β ) Q ¯ + α u t 1 u t 1 + β Q t 1
where Q t = ( q i j , t ) .
The conditional correlation at time t is expressed as:
ρ i j , t / q i i , t q j j , t         ,   i , j = 1 ,   2 ,   ,   n ,   and   i j
The correlation coefficient in the bivariate case is expressed as:
ρ 12 , t = ( 1 α β ) q ¯ 12 + α μ 1 , t 1 μ 2 , t 1 + β q 12 , t 1 [ ( 1 α β ) q ¯ 11 + α u 1 , t 1 2 + β q 11 , t 1 ]   [ ( 1 α β ) q ¯ 22 + α u 2 , t 1 2 + β q 22 , t 1 ]
The DCC-GARCH model is a forecasting model that quantifies volatility persistence for a sample period, while also providing dynamic correlation coefficients for the same period. We estimate the parameters using the maximum log-likelihood method which separates the equation into a function of variances and a function of correlations (Engle 2002).

3.4. Diebold-Yilmaz Volatility Spillover Index

The Diebold-Yilmaz volatility spillover index (Diebold and Yilmaz 2012) acts as an extension of a variance decomposition for a conventional VAR framework. Cross variance shares, or spillovers, are fractions of H-step-ahead error variances in projecting x i with original shocks to x j for i , j = 1 , 2 , , N such that i j . The subscripts of i and j in the spillover index denote the dependent and explanatory variables in the model, respectively. For example, when the S&P 500 Index is i , the SSE (or SZSE) would be j , etc. The H-step-ahead forecast error variance decompositions by θ i j g ( H ) for H = 1 ,   2 , , is given by:
θ i j g ( H ) = σ j j 1 h = 0 H 1 ( e i A h e j ) 2 h = 0 H 1 ( e i A h A h e i ) 2
where Σ is the variance matrix for the error vector ε, σjj is the standard deviation of the error term for the jth equation, and ei is the selection vector, with one as the ith element and zeros otherwise. As was explained, the sum of the elements in each row of the variance decomposition table is not equal to 1: j = 1 N   θ i j g ( H )  ≠ 1. For the purposes of properly converting the variance decomposition matrix to the spillover index, each entry of the variance decomposition matrix is normalized by the row sum as:
θ i j g ˜ ( H ) = θ i j g ( H ) j = 1 N θ i j g ( H )
By construction j = 1 N θ i j g ˜ ( H ) = 1 and i , j = 1 N θ i j g ˜ ( H ) = N .
The total Diebold-Yilmaz volatility spillover index is then denoted by:
S g ( H ) = i , j = 1   i j N θ i j g ˜ ( H ) i , j = 1 N θ i j g ˜ ( H ) 100 = i , j = 1   i j N θ i j g ˜ ( H ) N 100
The Diebold-Yilmaz spillover index acts as a gauge of volatility spillover, or volatility contagion.4

4. Results

Table 1 provides descriptive statistics of returns on the S&P 500, the Shanghai (SSE), and the Shenzhen (SZSE) Composite Indexes for each of the Bubble periods. Panel A provides results for the full period of the Dot-Com Bubble, and Panels B and C provide similar results for the Housing Bubble and the 2015 Chinese Bubble, respectively. In Panel A we also analyze sub-periods corresponding to the Build-Up, Bubble and Crash periods of the Dot-Com Bubble, and in Panel B we further analyze the Build-Up and Crash sub-periods of the Housing Bubble. The sample period for each respective bubble is: the Dot-Com Bubble, from 4 January 1995 to 30 November 2004; the Housing Bubble from 1 December 2004 to 16 March 2009; and the Chinese Bubble from 5 May 2014 to 15 September 2015.
Table 2 shows the correlations between daily returns on the three indices for each of the respective Bubble periods and respective sub-periods.
We calibrate the LPPL model using non-linear least squares and a Levenberg-Marquardt algorithm (LMA) (Liberatore 2010) to project the logarithmic oscillations of the log returns for the Shanghai and Shenzhen indexes. The purpose of the LMA is to reduce the standard residual error from the exponential non-linear squares initial solutions to a non-convex optimization for LPPL fitting. Essentially, a major reduction of residual standard error from the initial solutions signifies a bubble (LPPL) process, while no major reduction is simply an indicator of exponential growth in an index.
Table 3 provides results of our LPPL calibration of the 2015 Chinese Bubble. The time parameters are tstart, tend, and tc, which represent the first date in our data, the final date in our data and the estimate of the critical date, respectively. The other parameters of the model are m, the exponent of the power law growth, ω, the frequency of the fluctuations during the bubble, ϕ, the shift parameter, and A, B, and C, which are the value of log y t if the bubble lasts until the critical time, the decrease in log y t over the number of days until the bubble bursts, and the magnitude of the fluctuations around the exponential growth, respectively.
Panel a of Figure 1 shows the Shanghai stock index and Panel b of Figure 1 shows the Shenzhen index from 5 May 2014 to 15 September 2015. The green line shows the minimum value, the red line is the maximum value, and the yellow line indicates the computed initial critical time.
The results in Table 3 and Figure 1 indicate that while the Shanghai index conforms to mean-reverting, the LPPL bubble regime reveals that the Shenzhen index adheres to strict exponential growth. The disparity between the two Chinese indexes in volatility-confined LPPL bubble further supports the notion that volatility clustering is an inconsistent indicator of bubble contagion between the two countries. Differing results in this case reveal that volatility clustering between these two indexes mirror one another, but the log return series are disparate. Viewing contagion through the lens of volatility once again provides a completely different perspective than simply analyzing contagion through return or price movement correlations, even with only the Chinese indexes in a relatively localized Chinese bubble.
The data is made synchronous and stationary between stock indices by calculating the first log difference of the returns and synchronizing sample period dates across indices. The GARCH assumption of 1 > (α + β) is violated several times, indicating potential explosive processes.
Table 4 provides GARCH estimates for each of our return series in each of the bubble periods and sub-periods. In Panels A–D we provide results for the full period, the Build-Up, Bubble and Crash periods of the Dot-Com Bubble, in Panels E-G we provide similar results for the Housing Bubble, and in Panel H we provide results for the full-sample of the 2015 Chinese Bubble. The sample period for each respective bubble is: the Dot-Com Bubble, from 4 January 1995 to 30 November 2004; the Housing Bubble from 1 December 2004 to 16 March 2009; and the Chinese Bubble from 5 May 2014 to 15 September 2015.
Generally, the higher the α (lagged squared unexpected returns) coefficient and the lower the β (lagged return variance) coefficient, volatility-of-volatility is presumed to be more elevated. As an example, the GARCH estimates indicate that the α coefficient is statistically insignificant for the S&P 500 during the buildup and continuation of the Dot-Com Bubble, implying stable volatility. The results also show that the α coefficient for the Shanghai and Shenzhen indexes during the Housing Bubble crash is insignificant. Both the α and β coefficients are statistically significant for the Chinese indexes throughout the 2015 Chinese Bubble, this indicates explosive processes during this period.
Table 5 provides DCC estimates for each of the bubbles investigated. In Panels A–D we provide results for the full period, the Build-Up, Bubble and Crash periods of the Dot-Com Bubble, in Panels E–G we provide similar results for the Housing Bubble and in Panel H we provide results for the full-sample of the 2015 Chinese Bubble. The sample period for each respective bubble is: the Dot-Com Bubble, from 4 January 1995 to 30 November 2004; the Housing Bubble from 1 December 2004 to 16 March 2009; and the Chinese Bubble from 5 May 2014 to 15 September 2015.
The DCC estimates in Table 5 show that the volatility persistence in the indices varies in a cyclical manner as the three bubbles progress, but there is little to no consistency in the dynamic conditional correlations for the log return series. However, it is important to note that the dynamic conditional correlations are more helpful in analyzing returns or price contagion, rather than volatility contagion which we investigate using the Diebold-Yilmaz volatility spillover index.
Table 6 provides volatility spillover results using the model of Diebold and Yilmaz (2012) for each of the bubbles we investigate. In Panel A we provide results for the full period of the Dot-Com Bubble, and in Panels B and C we provide similar results for the Housing Bubble and the 2015 Chinese Bubble, respectively. The sample period for each respective bubble is: the Dot-Com Bubble, from 4 January 1995 to 30 November 2004; the Housing Bubble from 1 December 2004 to 16 March 2009; and the Chinese Bubble from 5 May 2014 to 15 September 2015.
The results of the Diebold-Yilmaz volatility spillover index in Table 6 provide a more accurate gauge of the volatility transmission and contagion that occur between the U.S. and Chinese indexes from bubble-to-bubble. The overall volatility spillover during the Dot-Com Bubble is negligible, but the spillover during the Housing Bubble and the 2015 Chinese Bubbles is highly significant, albeit the internal components have shifted. The spillover from the S&P 500 is reducing over time while the Shenzhen’s effect gradually increases. The volatility spillover results provide evidence that the overall volatility spillover effect is being maintained from the Housing Bubble. In other words, the Housing Bubble seems to be a pivotal event for volatility contagion in global markets going forward. This finding suggests that analysis of volatility transmission may need to be altered subsequent to this event.

5. Conclusions

In this paper, we use the setting of the three most recent financial crises that originated in the world’s two largest economies to show how asset bubbles, volatility clustering and financial contagion can be reliably identified and measured. Our main research questions are whether there was an increase in volatility persistence, vol of vol and volatility spillover during these times of financial turmoil. We find no significant evidence of a consistent contagion effect between the U.S. and Chinese stock indexes. Although the volatility persistence is high in both stock markets, the correlation coefficients are very unstable. The increase in correlations and overall volatility clustering that exist during the Housing Bubble could be a byproduct of QFII and QDII legislation that have made the Chinese economy less insulated. However, the high volatility of volatility, or “spikiness,” that was characteristic of both the Chinese indexes during the Dot-Com Bubble and the S&P 500 during the 2015 bubble, illustrate that the relationship between these equity markets is still very unpredictable. The cyclicality in the volatility-of-volatility ranging from the Dot-Com Bubble to the 2015 Chinese Bubble is largely reflected in the decoupled nature of the dynamic correlations.
Our findings provide evidence that international contagion and exposure during these periods is fundamentally weak, but the significance of policy implications is highlighted. In particular, we show how the liberalization of the Chinese stock market had the unintended consequence of initiating a bubble. Overall, as policy has evolved in QFII and QDII, the effects of “process switching” and economic conditions within these countries must be highlighted. The Lucas Critique supports the theoretical basis that with a transition in economic policy, the qualitative nature of economic variables is also altered. Together our results suggest that the co-movement of the Chinese and U.S. markets during financially idiosyncratic periods, such as bubbles, are not originally derived from the spread of volatility clustering alone. For example, it may be inferred that the contagion between the two economies is partially fueled by irrational noise.
One limitation of our study is that we have two bubble periods for the U.S. and only one for the Chinese Economy. Relatedly, the U.S. stock market is much more mature than that of the Chinese markets. It will be important to revisit this investigation when the Chinese market is more mature.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, N.B. and A.M.H.; Data curation, N.B.; Formal analysis, N.B. and A.F.; Methodology, N.B., A.F. and A.M.H.; Project administration, N.B. and A.M.H.; Software, N.B. and A.F.; Supervision, A.M.H.; Validation, N.B.; Writing—original draft, N.B., A.F. and A.M.H.; Writing—review & editing, N.B., A.F. and A.M.H. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

N.B. acknowledges support from WVU College of Business & Economics and the Department of Finance for the preliminary portion of this project. This funding was part of West Virginia University’s 2016 Summer Undergraduate Research Experiences (SURE).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

All data is from the Bloomberg terminal.

Acknowledgments

Nathan Boyd acknowledges helpful feedback from participants in West Virginia University’s 2016 Summer Undergraduate Research Experiences (SURE).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Calibration of LPPL Model for Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock Indexes

In the Shanghai stock index from 5 May 2014–15 September 2015 (Figure 1a), three consecutive peaks identified by implementing the price peaks algorithm (see Pele 2012) are:
i = 244   ( 6 / 4 / 2015 ) ,   j = 254   ( 05 / 27 / 2015 ) ,   and   k = 258   ( 6 / 2 / 2015 )
Using these peaks, the initial values of the parameters of the LPPL model are computed as follows:
ρ = j i k j = 254 244 258 254 = 2.5 Critical   time ,   t c = ρ k j ρ 1 = 260.6667 ,   ω = 2 π ln ( ρ ) = 6.857196 and   = π ω ln ( t c k ) = 12.64769 .
Initial values A = 8.41312 and B = −0.0035037 are computed by using the linear least-squares fit to an exponential function. The residual standard error is 0.06849.
Using the initial values, we fit the LPPL algorithm:
ln p ( t ) = A + B ( t c t ) m ( 1 + C   cos ( ω ln ( t c t ) + )
to the data.
The final values of the parameter are:
t c = 259 (6/03/2015), A = 8.436199, B = −0.005424, m = 0.940693 , C = 0.125600, ω = 7.386984 , = 2.106206 , with residual standard error of 0.04042.
The final parameter values and the substantial reduction of the residual standard error indicate that a bubble was likely in progress (see Liberatore 2010). The actual Shanghai index peak was on 6 December 2015.
In the Shenzhen stock index from 5 May 2014–15 September 2015 (Figure 1b), three consecutive peaks identified by implementing the price peaks algorithm (see Pele 2012) are:
i = 245   ( 5 / 13 / 2015 ) ,   j = 254   ( 5 / 27 / 2015 ) ,   and   k = 259   ( 6 / 3 / 2015 ) .
The initial parameter values are:
t c = 265.25 , A = 7.7651793, B = −0.00408038, m = 0.97478865 , C = 0.02102474, ω = 10.82082 , and = 16.423917 with residual standard error of 0.09078.
C 0 and there is not a significant reduction in the residual standard error. The actual Shenzhen index peak was on 12 June 2015.

Note

1
Garber (1990) is one of the earliest works that investigate bubbles.
2
Scherbina and Schlusche (2014) provide a nice survey on asset price bubbles.
3
Unreported Augmented Dickey-Fuller and Phillips-Perron tests of the sample returns strongly reject the null hypothesis of the presence of a unit root.
4
In a recent study, Akhtaruzzaman et al. (2021) investigate the spillover effects between from firms in the U.S. and firms in China and report that both U.S. and Chinese firms transmit more volatility than they receive.

References

  1. Agarwal, Vikas, Y. Esar Arisoy, and Narayan Y. Naik. 2017. Volatility of aggregate volatility and hedge fund returns. Journal of Financial Economics 125: 491–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Akhtaruzzaman, Md, Waleed Abdel-Qader, Helmi Hammami, and Syed Shams. 2021. Is China a source of financial contagion? Finance Research Letters 38: 101393. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bekaert, Geert, Michael Ehrmann, Marcel Fratzscher, and Arnaud Mehl. 2014. The Global Crisis and Equity Market Contagion. The Journal of Finance 69: 2597–649. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. BenMim, Imen, and Ahmed BenSaïda. 2019. Financial contagion across major stock markets: A study during crisis episodes. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 48: 187–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Brée, David S., and Nathan Lael Joseph. 2013. Testing for financial crashes using the log periodic power law model. International Review of Financial Analysis 30: 287–297. [Google Scholar]
  6. Case, Karl E., and Robert J. Shiller. 2003. Is there a bubble in the housing market? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2003: 299–362. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Chiang, Min-Hsien, and Li-Min Wang. 2011. Volatility contagion: A range-based volatility approach. Journal of Econometrics 165: 175–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Diebold, Francis X., and Kamil Yilmaz. 2009. Measuring financial asset return and volatility spillovers, with application to global equity markets. The Economic Journal 119: 158–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Diebold, Francis X., and Kamil Yilmaz. 2012. Better to give than to receive: Predictive directional measurement of volatility spillovers. International Journal of Forecasting 28: 57–66. [Google Scholar]
  10. Dimitriou, Dimitrios, Dimitris Kenourgios, and Theodore Simos. 2013. Global financial crisis and emerging stock market contagion: A multivariate FIAPARCH–DCC approach. International Review of Financial Analysis 30: 46–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Engle, Robert. 2002. Dynamic conditional correlation: A simple class of multivariate generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20: 339–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Flood, Robert P., and Robert J. Hodrick. 1986. Asset Price Volatility, Bubbles, and Process Switching. The Journal of Finance 41: 831. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Forbes, Kristin J., and Roberto Rigobon. 2002. No contagion, only interdependence: Measuring stock market comovements. Journal of Finance 57: 2223–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Garber, Peter M. 1990. Famous first bubbles. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 4: 35–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Gomez-Gonzalez, Jose Eduardo, Juliana Gamboa-Arbeláez, Jorge Hirs-Garzón, and Andrés Pinchao-Rosero. 2018. When Bubble Meets Bubble: Contagion in OECD Countries. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 56: 546–566. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Jin, Xiaoye, and Ximeng An. 2016. Global financial crisis and emerging stock market contagion: A volatility impulse response function approach. Research in International Business and Finance 36: 179–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Johansson, Anders C. 2010. China’s financial market integration with the world. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies 8: 293–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Liberatore, Vincenzo. 2010. Computational LPPL fit to financial bubbles. arXiv arXiv:1003.2920. [Google Scholar]
  19. Lin, Li, Ruo En Ren, and Didier Sornette. 2014. The volatility-confined LPPL model: A consistent model of ‘explosive’ financial bubbles with mean-reverting residuals. International Review of Financial Analysis 33: 210–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: A critique. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 1: 19–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Mandelbrot, Benoit B. 1963. The variation of certain speculative prices. Journal of Business 36: 392–417. [Google Scholar]
  22. Ofek, Eli, and Matthew Richardson. 2003. Dotcom mania: The rise and fall of internet stock prices. The Journal of Finance 58: 1113–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Pele, Daniel Traian. 2012. An LPPL Algorithm for estimating the critical time of a stock market bubble. Journal of Social and Economic Statistics 1: 14–22. [Google Scholar]
  24. Scherbina, Anna, and Bernd Schlusche. 2014. Asset price bubbles: A survey. Quantitative Finance 14: 589–604. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Shiller, Robert J. 2000. Irrational Exuberance. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
  26. Song, Guoxiang. 2020. The Drivers of the Great Bull Stock Market of 2015 in China: Evidence and Policy Implications. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies 18: 161–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Sornette, Didier, Peter Cauwels, and Georgi Smilyanov. 2018. Can we use volatility to diagnose financial bubbles? lessons from 40 historical bubbles. Quantitative Finance and Economics 2: 486–590. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Wang, Gang-Jin, Chi Xie, Min Lin, and H. Eugene Stanley. 2017. Stock market contagion during the global financial crisis: A multiscale approach. Finance Research Letters 22: 163–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Yousaf, Imran, Shoaib Ali, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2020a. Return and Volatility Transmission between World-Leading and Latin American Stock Markets: Portfolio Implications. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Zeng, Fanhua, Wei-Chiao Huang, and James Hueng. 2016. On Chinese Government’s Stock Market Rescue Efforts in 2015. ME Modern Economy 7: 411–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Zhang, Qunzhi, Didier Sornette, Mehmet Balcilar, Rangan Gupta, Zeynel Abidin Ozdemir, and Hakan Yetkiner. 2016. LPPLS bubble indicators over two centuries of the S&P 500 index. Physica A: statistical Mechanics and Its Applications 458: 126–39. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. LPPL model calibration for: (a) The Shanghai stock index and (b) The Shenzhen stock index
Figure 1. LPPL model calibration for: (a) The Shanghai stock index and (b) The Shenzhen stock index
Jrfm 14 00229 g001
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics of Returns Series.
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics of Returns Series.
Panel A: Dot-Com Bubble
Full Bubble period Build-Up periodBubble periodCrash period
S&P 500SSESZSES&P 500SSESZSES&P 500SSESZSES&P 500SSESZSE
Mean0.0410.0320.0390.0960.1260.2170.0810.0570.039−0.015−0.033−0.051
Median0.0580.0180.0560.0900.0170.2730.0920.0440.0160.0040.0010.016
Std. Dev.1.1821.9242.0110.6912.8582.8921.3151.8101.9861.2711.3301.395
Kurtosis3.20323.63217.0693.23218.72314.6143.6374.2084.0741.6566.2735.775
Skewness−0.0660.9230.307−0.1931.1870.486−0.294−0.435−0.5720.1690.6670.407
Minimum−7.113−17.905−18.887−3.131−17.905−18.887−7.113−9.246−10.172−5.047−6.543−6.817
Maximum5.57426.99324.9043.76126.99324.9045.4028.6658.6825.5749.4019.244
N231123112311523523523741741741104710471047
Panel B: Housing Bubble
Full Bubble periodBuild-Up periodCrash period
S&P 500SSESZSES&P 500SSESZSES&P 500SSESZSE
Mean−0.0440.0460.0710.0310.1950.216−0.169−0.202−0.172
Median0.0700.1370.2430.0830.2070.3080.008−0.126−0.008
Std. Dev.1.5752.1272.2640.7111.7011.8412.3992.6762.817
Kurtosis14.7973.4072.7752.3364.3563.6615.7301.8171.298
Skewness−0.748−0.402−0.601−0.537−0.601−0.606−0.400−0.116−0.404
Minimum−13.799−12.764−12.697−3.534−9.256−8.930−13.799−12.764−12.697
Maximum10.9579.0348.5152.1347.8908.35110.9579.0348.515
N100510051005628628628377377377
Panel C: 2015 Chinese Bubble
Full Bubble period
S&P 500SSESZSE
Mean0.0150.1200.129
Median0.0420.1790.475
Std. Dev.0.8492.1232.231
Kurtosis3.3063.6672.539
Skewness−0.382−0.977−1.098
Minimum−4.021−8.873−8.195
Maximum3.8296.0405.259
N327327327
Table 2. Correlations between Return Series.
Table 2. Correlations between Return Series.
Panel A: Dot-Com Bubble
Full Bubble periodBuild-Up periodBubble periodCrash period
S&P 500SSES&P 500SSES&P 500SSES&P 500SSE
SSE−0.0332 −0.1038 −0.0452 0.0027
SZSE−0.02900.8983−0.13090.8253−0.02620.96180.00940.9759
Panel B: Housing Bubble
Full Bubble period Build-Up period Crash period
S&P 500SSE S&P 500SSE S&P 500SSE
SSE0.0495 0.0864 0.0341
SZSE0.01900.9285 0.06800.9303 −0.00240.9266
Panel C: 2015 Chinese Bubble
Full Bubble period
S&P 500SSE
SSE0.2024
SZSE0.18270.8335
Table 3. 2015 Chinese Bubble LPPL Calibration.
Table 3. 2015 Chinese Bubble LPPL Calibration.
tstarttendtcmωϕABC
SSE5 May 201415 September 20153 June 20150.9417.387−2.1068.436−0.0040.126
SZSE5 May 201415 September 201510 June 20150.97510.821−16.4207.765−0.0040.021
Table 4. GARCH Estimates.
Table 4. GARCH Estimates.
Panel A: Dot-Com Bubble—Full Period
S&P 500SSESZSE
αβαΒAβ
0.0717 ***0.9243 ***0.1209 ***0.8898 ***0.1275 ***0.8765 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Panel B: Dot-Com Bubble—Build-Up Period
S&P 500SSESZSE
αβαβAβ
0.0354 *0.9529 ***0.1285 **0.4773 ***0.1766 **0.494 ***
(0.069)(0.000)(0.033)(0.000)(0.011)(0.000)
Panel C: Dot-Com Bubble—Mid-Bubble Period
S&P 500SSESZSE
αβαβαβ
0.0922 *0.7957 ***0.1812 **0.7695 ***0.2082 ***0.7195 ***
(0.091)(0.000)(0.034)(0.000)(0.003)(0.000)
Panel D: Dot-Com Bubble—Crash Period
S&P 500SSESZSE
αβAβαβ
0.0866 ***0.9047 ***0.1538 ***0.8041 ***0.1583 ***0.8121 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.001)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Panel E: Housing Bubble—Full Period
S&P 500SSESZSE
αβAβαβ
0.0971 ***0.8985 ***0.0496 ***0.9498 ***0.0522 ***0.9458 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Panel F: Housing Bubble—Build-Up Period
S&P 500SSESZSE
αβAβαβ
0.0485 ***0.8828 ***0.0716 ***0.9243 ***0.0717 ***0.9215 ***
(0.004)(0.000)(0.002)(0.000)(0.006)(0.000)
Panel G: Housing Bubble—Crash Period
S&P 500SSESZSE
αβAβαβ
0.1220 ***0.8750 ***0.02380.8791 ***0.02400.9476 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.471)(0.000)(0.322)(0.000)
Panel H: 2015 Chinese Bubble—Full Period
S&P 500SSESZSE
αβAβαβ
0.2206 ***0.6594 ***0.1634 ***0.8548 ***0.1096 ***0.8942 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.001)(0.000)(0.000)
Note: *, **, *** denotes significance at the 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
Table 5. DCC Estimates.
Table 5. DCC Estimates.
Panel A: Dot-Com Bubble-Full Period
S&P 500-SSES&P 500-SZSE
aBab
0.0046 ***−0.9683 ***−0.0002 0.7854
(0.000)(0.000)N/AN/A
Panel B: Dot-Com Bubble—Build-Up Period
S&P 500-SSES&P 500-SZSE
aBab
0.0126 0.8999 ***0.0147 0.8928 ***
(0.344)(0.000)(0.390)(0.000)
Panel C: Dot-Com Bubble—Mid-Bubble Period
S&P 500-SSES&P 500-SZSE
aBab
−0.0106 ***1.0003 ***−0.0227 ***0.9161 ***
(0.008)(0.000)(0.004)(0.000)
Panel D: Dot-Com Bubble—Crash Period
S&P 500-SSES&P 500-SZSE
aBab
−0.0016 ***1.0402 ***0.0362 −0.1231
(0.000)(0.000)(0.384)(0.867)
Panel E: Housing Bubble—Full Period
S&P 500-SSES&P 500-SZSE
aBab
0.0115 0.9498 ***0.00900.8650 *
(0.326)(0.000) (0.664)(0.057)
Panel F: Housing Bubble—Build-Up Period
S&P 500-SSES&P 500-SZSE
aBab
0.0136 0.5674 −0.0021 0.8499
(0.733)(0.539)(0.915)(0.267)
Panel G: Housing Bubble—Crash Period
S&P 500-SSES&P 500-SZSE
aBab
0.0373 0.8639 ***0.0496 0.7606 ***
(0.262)(0.000)(0.299)(0.001)
Panel H: 2015 Chinese Bubble—Full Period
S&P 500-SSES&P 500-SZSE
aBab
0.0732 0.7393 ***0.0277 0.8889 ***
(0.121)(0.000) (0.347)(0.000)
Note: *, *** denotes significance at the 10% and 1%, respectively.
Table 6. Volatility Spillover Results.
Table 6. Volatility Spillover Results.
Panel A: Dot-Com Bubble
S&P 500SSESZSEFrom Others
S&P 50099.60.40.00.4
SSE0.499.20.40.8
SZSE0.379.620.279.8
Contribution to others0.679.90.581.0
Contribution including own100.2179.120.727.0%
Panel B: Housing Bubble
S&P 500SSESZSEFrom Others
S&P 50097.92.10.02.1
SSE3.596.00.44.0
SZSE2.881.815.484.6
Contribution to others6.383.90.590.7
Contribution including own104.2179.915.930.2%
Panel C: 2015 Chinese Bubble
S&P 500SSESZSEFrom Others
S&P 50091.18.70.28.9
SSE2.595.61.94.4
SZSE4.272.822.977.1
Contribution to others6.781.52.290.5
Contribution including own97.8177.125.130.2%
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Burks, N.; Fadahunsi, A.; Hibbert, A.M. Financial Contagion: A Tale of Three Bubbles. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14, 229. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/jrfm14050229

AMA Style

Burks N, Fadahunsi A, Hibbert AM. Financial Contagion: A Tale of Three Bubbles. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2021; 14(5):229. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/jrfm14050229

Chicago/Turabian Style

Burks, Nathan, Adetokunbo Fadahunsi, and Ann Marie Hibbert. 2021. "Financial Contagion: A Tale of Three Bubbles" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 14, no. 5: 229. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/jrfm14050229

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop