Next Article in Journal
Residents’ Experiences of Privacy and Comfort in Multi-Storey Apartment Dwellings in Subtropical Brisbane
Previous Article in Journal
Development of the Social Inventory Database in Thailand Using Input–Output Analysis
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Harnessing the Sun and Wind for Economic Development? An Economy-Wide Assessment for Egypt

by
Perrihan Al-Riffai
1,†,
Julian Blohmke
2,†,
Clemens Breisinger
1,† and
Manfred Wiebelt
3,*,†
1
International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), Washington, DC 20006-1002, USA
2
International Centre for Integrated Assessment and Sustainable Development, Maastricht University, 6211 LK Maastricht, The Netherlands
3
Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Kiellinie 66, 24105 Kiel, Germany
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
These authors contributed equally to this work.
Sustainability 2015, 7(6), 7714-7740; https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su7067714
Submission received: 9 April 2015 / Revised: 2 June 2015 / Accepted: 11 June 2015 / Published: 17 June 2015

Abstract

:
While the recent political transition in Egypt has delayed much-needed policy reforms, our paper suggests that under certain conditions, fostering the national renewable energy strategy may be a promising way of giving an ailing economy an urgently needed impetus. Based on the literature and results of a renewable-energy focused computable general equilibrium model, we recommend that Egypt supports the generation of wind power. While some energy may be exported to generate foreign exchange, a substantial part of the newly produced energy should be sold domestically to ease existing supply constraints and to avoid Dutch disease effects. In addition, and in order to maximize the benefits of renewable energy sources, the renewable energy strategy should be accompanied by a (further) reduction of energy subsidies. Finally, lessons from other countries suggest that sound institutions; appropriate, clear and lasting regulations; careful technology transfer; and cross-ministerial coordination are important for success.

1. Introduction

The global debate on renewable energies often revolves around reducing carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions as one option to mitigate climate change. The power sector constitutes 41% of global CO2 emissions [1], and the world is not on track to realize the 2020 interim CO2 emission reduction targets [2]. The energy-related global carbon emissions are largely driven by the increasing volume derived from within developing countries, including many Arab countries [1,3]. Limiting the increase of carbon emissions from energy generation in these countries is therefore indispensable for achieving the ambitious targets [4,5]. However, because economic development requires energy, especially at earlier stages, balancing the rising demand for energy with a need to limit CO2 emissions is one of the key climate change mitigation challenges [6,7]. Together with the increase in energy efficiency, which has huge potential to mitigate carbon emissions, the rapid diffusion of renewable energy technologies (RET) is thus considered the second most important mitigation option [8].
In addition to reducing CO2 emissions, the development of renewable energies may also have positive effects on countries’ economic development. The early and broad diffusion of RET would not only slow down the increase of global carbon emission but also allow economies to “leapfrog” over the use of conventional energy resources like oil, coal, or gas toward production technologies reliant on more climate-friendly power [9,10]. Diversifying electricity generation through RET may be particularly important in light of potentially rising future energy costs and geopolitical risks related to mineral resources (energy security). In addition, renewable energies may create jobs and thus foster economic development. Several studies to date have been comparing job creation effects of RET deployment with conventional power generation (see [11]). The general picture shows that, on a per-megawatt basis, there are more jobs being created in solar and wind technology deployment than in conventional power technology. Finally, there may be other associated socioeconomic benefits, including the protection of resources, the reduction of air pollution, and improved health outcomes.
One of the main criticisms of renewable energies is that they are often not cost competitive and thus have to be subsidized. However, production costs for windmills and solar panels have decreased (in part because of subsidies) and—depending on location and the relevant opportunity costs for conventional energy—energy production from renewables can be profitable [12]. As a result, several emerging economies are stepping up efforts in RET deployment [13]. China, for example, has been strengthening its renewables policies and targets since 2012; other countries, including several Arab countries, have developed renewable energy strategies and show considerable potential toward achieving them [14]. However, for renewable development to work, challenges such as the lack of transparency, political uncertainty, and regional economic disparities, need to be resolved in order to attract and retain investors [14].
Egypt is one of the Arab countries that laid out ambitious plans for developing RET. In fact, one of the reasons for developing RET is the hope that it will help promote economic growth and job creation. This is particularly important since recent political events have slowed down economic growth prospects and increased unemployment and poverty [15,16]. Poverty has increased by nearly 50% in the past 15 years from a low of 16.7% (9.9 million people) in 1996 to 21.6% in 2009 and 25.2% (21 million) in 2011 [17]. Moreover, although poverty remained highest in rural areas, the period 2009–2011 saw the fastest rate of increase in urban areas, where poverty grew by nearly 40%.
The objective of this paper is to assess how exactly RET can support economic development in Egypt and thus also provide lessons for other countries. In order to provide answers to these questions, the remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 examines the status quo of energy in Egypt as well as the potential and plans for renewables. Section 3 discusses the data and model. Section 4 presents the key results and Section 5 concludes.

2. Energy in Egypt: Status Quo, Potential and Plans for Renewables

2.1. Status Quo

Energy production and use has been growing rapidly in Egypt over the past years. Oil and natural gas are the most important natural resources in Egypt’s natural assets [15]. Gas production reached 2.17 trillion cubic feet (tcf) in 2011. Despite this strong growth in gas production, the existing capacity is still insufficient to meet export and domestic demand.
The oil sector presents a similar picture. Even though Egypt continuously discovers more reserves—which increased from 3.7 billion barrels in 2010 to 4.4 billion barrels in 2012—it produced only 815,000 barrels per day (2011), which shows decline. At the same time, domestic oil consumption has grown to about the same amount as oil production in 2011 [18].
Egypt’s current installed capacity for electricity generation consists of 88% fossil-fuel-based technologies and 12% renewable energy technologies, of which 83% is hydropower [19]. Since all major hydropower sites have been developed there is little potential to expand electricity production from hydropower [20]. In places where 99% of households have access to the electricity system, the peak load growth rate averaged 7.5% per year from 2005 to 2010 [20,21]. In order to satisfy demand increase, the power sector expanded its installed capacity to roughly 25,000 megawatts by the end of 2010. Those efforts were insufficient to fully meet high and rising demand, however, and have led to widespread electricity shortages across the country [20]. Natural gas has traditionally comprised nearly 100% of conventional supply but dropped to roughly 80% in 2010 because of the insufficient supply of gas [20]. Heavy fuel oil has been burned to compensate for the gas shortage in the power sector.

2.2. Potential for Renewables

Due to the limited availability of fossil fuels in the power sector and the increasing cost of electricity supply, the government’s interest in the diversification of the energy mix has been evolving rapidly over the past few years. Egypt has solar irradiation and appropriate wind conditions—the prerequisites to producing electricity from renewable sources. The country has large deserts that are sparsely populated and thus, in principle, both solar and wind technologies have potential for widespread application. The annual direct normal solar irradiance ranges from 2000 kilowatt hours per square meter (kWh/m2) to 3200 kWh/m2 across the country, with a steady daily profile of approximately 9–11 h of sunlight [20]. Wind conditions are also favorable in the Gulf of Suez reaching wind speeds of 7–8 meters per second. The lower cost of wind technologies compared to solar power, due to relatively high wind speed potentials, especially in the western part of the Gulf of Suez [13], favor the adoption and proliferation of wind technologies in Egypt’s energy mix.
Moreover, from an economic point of view, renewable technologies in Egypt are competitive with conventional technologies in both the MENA region and Europe (see Figure 1).
Figure 1. Range of levelized cost of electricity for different technologies in MENA and Europe (€/kWh). Note: LCOE = levelized cost of electricity; CSP = concentrating solar power; and PV = photovoltaic; Source: Authors’ calculations based on Desertec Industrial Initiative [22]. The LCOE calculation takes into account country specific solar irradiation and wind speed figures affecting the LCOE on country level.
Figure 1. Range of levelized cost of electricity for different technologies in MENA and Europe (€/kWh). Note: LCOE = levelized cost of electricity; CSP = concentrating solar power; and PV = photovoltaic; Source: Authors’ calculations based on Desertec Industrial Initiative [22]. The LCOE calculation takes into account country specific solar irradiation and wind speed figures affecting the LCOE on country level.
Sustainability 07 07714 g001
The estimated LCOE of Egyptian power generation from existing power plants (including hydro, natural gas, and fuel oil) is at US$0.11/kWh. Those of onshore wind energy generation are at US$0.06/kWh, utility scale solar photovoltaic (PV) at US$0.11/kWh, and concentrated solar power (CSP) costs US$0.16/kWh. The LCOE has been calculated also for other MENA countries taking into account respective solar irradiation and average wind speed. This illustrates that wind technology specifically is competitive with conventional power generation technologies in Egypt. The figures we use [22] are in that range and also confirm that wind technology is competitive with conventional power, unlike PV and CSP.

2.3. Egypt’s Renewable Energy Strategy

In response to the existing opportunities and challenges due to energy shortages in the energy sector, the Egyptian Supreme Council of Energy has approved a strategy that aims to increase the share of renewable energy to 20% of electricity overall by 2020, with 12% coming from solar and wind technologies and 8% from hydropower [12,23]. Specifically, Egypt’s wind target is set at roughly 7200 megawatts by 2020 and is clearly prioritized due to its lower cost compared to solar technologies [12]. Solar development targets are less pronounced and not as ambitious with a solar PV target at 220 megawatts by 2020 and 1100 megawatts of CSP. Egypt announced a further 2027 target of 2800 MW of CSP and 700 MW of PV [24]. The lower solar PV target is also due to the fact that solar technology is more expensive relative to wind technology.
Achieving these targets will require swift mid-term development of solar and wind power plants. In order to meet this requirement, the current installed capacity of wind electricity generation needs to grow by 13 times, PV by 15 times, and CSP by 55 times [19].
The process by which to achieve these targets is in two parts [24,25]. First, a competitive bidding process for projects shall be organized, leading to long-term power purchase agreements (PPA) of 20 to 25 years. Second, there shall be feed-in tariffs (FiT) determined based on the results of the bidding process. The FiT intend to support small and medium developers with capacities of up to 50 MW. The NREA has also increased efforts to incentivize private sector engagement in the emerging renewable energy sector. Proposed measures include favorable permits and land-use agreements for renewable energy project developers, custom-duty exemptions, local content awards in tendering processes, and power generation licenses from the national utility company.
Solar and wind technologies in Egypt are not only expected to contribute to fuel savings and CO2 reductions but also to meet the increasing electricity demand in the country (annual growth rate of peak load averaged between 2005 and 2010 at 7.5% per annum; [20]) and may cover part of the electricity demand in Europe, as proposed, for example, by the Desertec vision [26].
In the following sections, we will investigate how these proposed renewable energy plans and the Egyptian power sector’s shift toward renewable energy technologies will impact the country’s overall economic development and welfare situation.

3. Modeling the Economy-Wide Effects of Investing in Renewable Energy

Recent studies assessed energy demand and supply for MENA countries till 2030 by using energy-economic models with an annual time resolution [27] or “characteristic” time periods (time slices) over the year to represent supply and demand matches over the year [28], or by leaving out intermittence in their energy module in order to reduce complexity [29]. Given that those studies are interested in macroeconomic and countrywide effects, they do not take into account country specific power demand patterns (supply and demand of power per hour of the day). By following the approach of annual time resolution, it is not possible account for the different technology characteristics (dispatch time and power storage infrastructure requirements) as well as precise power grid investments for the necessary grid expansion. Grid costs are included as an additional investment premium for each technology. This paper uses the power technology expansion figures from the national renewable energy policy targets because we explicitly want to assess the economy-wide effects of Egypt’s Renewable Energy Strategy. Thus, we are confined to using the given power technology investment figures from the Government of Egypt.

3.1. The Database: A Renewable-Energy-Focused Social Accounting Matrix

The basis for our assessment of renewable energy investments in Egypt is a social accounting matrix (SAM) we developed. The SAM represents the structure of the Egyptian economy and importantly describes the linkages between various renewable energy sectors, other sectors of the economy, institutions, and other countries (through trade) [30]. The SAM is based on the latest published supply and use tables compiled by the Central Agency for Public Mobilization and Statistics (CAPMAS) for 2008/09 and is complemented with data from the Household Income, Expenditure, and Consumption Survey for the same year [31] as well as data on the economically active population in 2007 [32]. The SAM includes production, intermediate use, final demands, sectoral capital earnings, and sectoral expenditures on wages and salaries, as well as the distribution of factor income to households and the redistribution of income between the private and public sector. Key aspects of the Egyptian economy in 2008 will be discussed below.
The input–output data compiled by CAPMAS [33] do not include statistics on renewable electricity supply technologies; rather the electricity sector in the benchmark data is an aggregate of existing renewable and conventional technologies. We therefore calculated the input requirements for the renewable electricity technologies based on additional data sources, allowing us to disaggregate the aggregate electricity sector into renewable and conventional subcomponents, as in Desertec Industrial Initiative [22] and Calzadilla et al. [34]. We conduct our disaggregation using data from an industry survey conducted by Dii that describes cost and technological characteristics of PV, CSP, and wind electricity generation technologies (see Table 1 and Table 2). The different inputs; capital, land, and labor for each technology have been assessed on a component level in order to specify the linkage of each input to other sectors in the economy.
Table 1. Production cost estimates for renewable equipment manufacturing (EUR/kW).
Table 1. Production cost estimates for renewable equipment manufacturing (EUR/kW).
PVCSPWIND
Minerals and mineral products 464
Rubber, plastic products 579
Metals and metal products150678289
Electronic equipment810355
Machinery and other equipment260919459
Vehicles and transport equipment 224
Construction9058379
Other transport 21515
Business services150997134
Total146047901200
Note: PV stands for photovoltaic power; CSP for concentrated solar power; and WIND for wind power. Source: [22].
Table 2. Production cost estimates for renewable electricity generation (EUR/kW).
Table 2. Production cost estimates for renewable electricity generation (EUR/kW).
PVCSPWIND
Electronic equipment7.5
Machinery and other equipment4.221.710.8
Water 3.8
Business services0.78.13.2
Insurance5.026.63.2
Labor remuneration21.032.63.6
Capital rental102.2335.384.0
Land rental1.60.23.2
Total142.2428.3108.0
Note: PV stands for photovoltaic power; CSP for concentrated solar power; and WIND for wind power. Source: [22].
To generate cost shares for renewable equipment manufacturing, we calculated the weighted cost for each technology from the input–output data using the technology components for each technology in Table 1 as weights. The technology of equipment manufacturing and the electricity generation phase of the technology, and the consumption of further capital are two separate groups of vectors. This allows us to compile input cost shares for each technology and to separate the aggregate electricity generation sector into conventional and renewable subsectors. The input cost shares for all electricity-generating technologies are given in Table 3.
Table 3. Benchmark cost shares for renewable equipment manufacturing, all other manufacturing, and electricity generation.
Table 3. Benchmark cost shares for renewable equipment manufacturing, all other manufacturing, and electricity generation.
Equipment manufacturingElectricity generation
PVCSPWINDOther manu.PVCSPWINDConventional
Intermediates0.650.560.650.690.120.140.160.55
Energy 0.10
Primary education0.050.060.050.030.090.050.020.09
Secondary education0.020.020.020.010.040.020.010.04
Tertiary education0.010.010.010.010.010.010.000.01
Capital0.280.350.270.250.720.780.780.21
Land0.000.000.000.000.010.000.030.00
Total1.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.00
Note: PV stands for photovoltaic power, CSP for concentrated solar power, and WIND for wind power. Source: Authors’ calculations based on [22,33].
Overall, the key differences between renewable and conventional electricity technologies are that the renewable energy technologies are more capital intensive and less energy intensive than the conventional electricity generating technology. Renewable energy technologies are also somewhat less labor intensive and require significantly less intermediate inputs. Moreover, our data suggest that the renewable equipment manufacturing sectors, especially CSP, have a higher proportion of value added compared to the broader manufacturing sector. Yet, most of the value added that will be generated in the renewable sectors is capital income on foreign direct investment that will be repatriated to foreign owners of the capital stock.

3.2. The Model: A Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Model

To assess the potential impacts of alternative renewable investment schemes for Egypt, we build a multi-sector dynamic computable general equilibrium (DCGE) model following the standard DCGE model described in Diao and Thurlow (2012) [35]. In the following, we will describe the most important features of the model as they relate to Egypt and our specific modifications and simulations. The full set of equations and a description of variables and parameters can be found in Appendix A.
The Egyptian economy is modeled as a competitive economy with flexible prices and market conditions. Agents represented in the model are consumers, who maximize utility; producers, who maximize profits; and the government. Egypt is connected with the rest of the world via bilateral trade flows, remittances, and other transfers.
To reflect the fact that investments in windmills and solar panels take place over a longer period of time, the analytical framework is recursively dynamic—which means that the evolution of the economy over time is described by a sequence of single-period static equilibriums connected through capital accumulation, changes in factor supply, and sector specific technical progress. The economic structure, including energy production from renewables, is fully specified and covers production, investment, and final consumption by consumers and the government. Policy instruments are taxes, subsidies, or quantity constraints in factor markets, product markets, and international trade. The model results show relative changes to a reference scenario that also needs to be defined.
Producers of renewable energy and those of other goods and services (including one agricultural sector, 23 industrial sectors, and two service sectors) are price takers in output and input markets and maximize profits using constant returns to scale technologies. For all sectors, except renewable energy producers, the production function consists of a constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) aggregate of capital and labor (and land in agriculture and renewables) nested within a Leontief aggregate of all other inputs (that is, intermediate demand is determined by fixed technology coefficients, or Leontief demand:
X i = Λ i ( f α i f V i f ρ i ) 1 / ρ i
where X is the quantity of output of sector i, Λ is the total factor productivity (TFP), V is the quantity of demand for each factor f (labor, capital, land), and α is a share parameter of factor f used for the production of commodity i. For renewable energy production, we assume a Leontief technology, where the entire domestic capital–labor–land nest is combined with foreign direct investment (FDI), which is determined exogenously by foreign investors.
We model separate domestic manufacturing sectors that produce capital equipment for renewable energy generation (for example, wind turbine blades, nacelles, solar panel and inverter manufacturers). Producers of renewable energy will choose to purchase outputs from these manufacturing sectors, rather than purchasing imported renewable energy capital goods. Profit maximization implies that factor payments equal average production revenues. Labor, capital, and land are fixed, implying full employment and intersectoral mobility, except for capital and land, which are assumed to be immobile across sectors. New capital from past investment is allocated to sectors according to profit rate differentials under a “putty–clay” specification. This means that once capital stocks have been invested it is difficult to transfer them to other uses. The same holds true for land in agriculture and in renewable electricity sectors. This means that as renewable electricity sectors expand, they generate additional demand for labor, which then affects economy-wide wages and production in other sectors by increasing labor competition. Based on the 2008/09 Household Income, Expenditure and Consumption Survey (HIECS), labor markets are segmented across three skill groups: (1) low-skilled workers with primary education; (2) semi-skilled workers with secondary education; and (3) skilled workers who have completed tertiary schooling.
Factor incomes are distributed to households using fixed income shares on households’ initial factor endowments. Incomes are then saved (based on marginal propensities to save) or spent on consumption (according to marginal budget shares). Household savings and foreign capital inflows are collected in a national savings pool and used to finance investment demand (meaning a savings-driven investment closure). Finally, prices equilibrate product markets so that demand for each commodity equals supply. The model therefore links production patterns to household factor incomes through changes in factor employment and returns.
Households maximize a Cobb-Douglas utility function so that budget shares are constant. Households are disaggregated across rural/urban and by per capita expenditure quintiles, giving a total of 10 representative households in the full DCGE model. Households pay taxes to the government based on fixed direct and indirect tax rates. Tax revenues finance exogenous recurrent spending and transfers to households, resulting in an endogenous fiscal deficit. Finally, the model includes a simple consumption-side microsimulation module where each respondent in HIECS is linked to their corresponding representative household in the DCGE model. Changes in commodity prices and each household group’s consumption spending are passed down from the DCGE model to the survey respondents, where their total per capita consumption and poverty measures are recalculated.
International trade is captured by allowing production and consumption to shift imperfectly between domestic and foreign markets, depending on the relative prices of imports, exports, and domestic goods (inclusive of relevant sales, trade taxes, and subsidies). This specification captures differences in domestic and foreign products and allows for observed two-way trade. However, Egypt is still considered a small economy, such that world prices are fixed and the real exchange rate (that is, price index of tradable to nontradable goods) adjusts to maintain a fixed current account balance.
Renewable electricity expansion is assumed to be driven entirely by foreign direct investment, and all profits generated in the renewable sectors are remitted abroad. The decision to invest is thus resolved exogenously by foreign investors FDI in renewable electricity and in manufacturing sectors will expand the capital stock for renewables. This expansion in resources will cause growth rate in renewables to increase in all renewable energy scenarios. Renewable energy producers must, however, compete with other sectors for intermediate inputs and labor resources. In the DCGE model, we assume full employment, which means that total labor supplies are fixed and increasing labor demand raises workers’ wages, thereby leading to a reallocation of workers from the non-renewables to the renewables sectors. Ultimately, the trade-offs from renewables production will generally be smaller than the gains from new investments in the renewables industry. As a result, national GDP growth rates will increase in most renewable energy scenarios. Moreover, we assume that all renewable electricity is exported.
We initially create the renewable electricity and renewable equipment manufacturing sectors representing their current capacities (see next section) then smoothly increase renewable energy production over the period 2008–2020, reflecting the likely gradual expansion of the industry. The wind target in Egypt is set to 7200 megawatts by 2020 and is clearly prioritized for its lower cost compared to solar technologies [12]. Solar development targets are less pronounced and not that ambitious with a solar PV target at 220 megawatts by 2020 and 1100 megawatts of concentrated solar power.
The Egypt DCGE model is first run forward using the 2008–2020 period, assuming no expansion in renewable electricity production. This produces a reference scenario against which to assess Egypt’s renewables strategy. For this, we first calibrate the Egypt DCGE model to track observed trends in key demographic and macroeconomic indicators. Population growth and growth of unskilled, medium-skilled, and high-skilled labor are all set at 2% per year during 2008–2020. We exclude an expansion of agricultural land to capture rising population density in rural areas. In order to achieve recently observed growth rates in GDP, total factor productivity growth is set to 0.5% for agriculture and 1.6% for industry per year during the simulation period. Thus, the baseline scenario also captures the recent poor performance of the Egyptian economy. Then in the renewables simulations we expand the size of the renewable electricity and renewable equipment subsectors to produce the above mentioned target values.
When interpreting these results, it is important to keep several well-known weaknesses of DCGE models in mind. While none of the following limitations of the model presented in this paper is likely to alter the key messages, it is important to highlight them. First, like any other model, the DCGE is very data intensive. While it is a major strength of this type of model to reconcile data from different sources, such as balance of payments data, national accounts and household surveys, it is also perhaps their major weakness. Second, the assumption of full employment and flexible wages in Egypt can be justified by the fact that producing renewable energy equipment and operating renewable energy plants require specific skills, which unemployed people may not have. Thus hiring people to support renewable energy driven growth will have to be done from the existing workforce.

4. Potential Impacts of Investing in Renewable Energy Projects

4.1. Renewables in the Economy-Wide Context

Table 4 shows the structure of the Egyptian economy in 2008, which is the initial starting point for the model. Given our focus on renewable energy, employment generation, and poverty reduction, we are interested in how Egypt’s renewable energy strategy affects the income earned by each household as well as how it is earned. The SAM provides the information needed to answer both questions. The former is what is referred to as the functional distribution of income—the returns to factors—and the latter is the size distribution of income—how the factor returns are distributed (and redistributed) among households (and the government and the rest of the world).
Table 4. Structure of Egypt’s economy, 2008.
Table 4. Structure of Egypt’s economy, 2008.
Sectors Share of total (%)Export intensity (%)Import penetration (%)
GDPEmploymentExportsImports
1-26Total100.00100.00100.00100.0016.5920.14
1Agriculture13.4131.822.708.004.0013.70
2-24Industry36.9522.0563.6382.2022.0031.76
2Mining15.830.1619.406.4031.9016.00
3-18Manufacturing14.9211.0139.7072.8023.6241.71
3Food processing3.612.074.106.0010.3018.00
4-18Other manufacturing11.318.9435.6066.8027.6247.37
4-6Renewable equipment manufacturing0.180.050.700.60 36.21
4PV equipment0.010.000.000.00 49.50
5CSP equipment0.030.010.100.10 30.30
6Wind equipment0.150.040.600.50 36.70
12Petroleum and petroleum processing2.050.7914.904.4045.7024.40
19-23Utilities1.711.272.402.6012.4415.96
19-22Electricity1.330.942.300.6015.105.29
19-21Renewable electricity0.040.002.200.00100.00
19PV electricity0.000.000.100.00100.00
20CSP electricity0.010.000.300.00100.00
21Wind electricity0.040.001.800.00100.00
22Conventional electricity1.290.930.100.600.805.30
23Water0.380.340.102.001.9039.50
24Construction4.509.601.500.403.901.40
25-26Services49.6446.1333.509.300.075.10
25Private services18.3522.0731.102.2029.403.40
26Government services31.2924.072.407.101.706.00
Note: Sector summaries in bold type. Source: Results from the Egypt DCGE model.
Agriculture generates only 13% of Egypt’s gross domestic product but more than 30% of total employment. Most farmers are smallholders with low education levels; more than 17% of total low-skilled labor income is generated in agriculture. However, Egypt as a whole relies on imported food, which accounts for 14% of total imports and 18% of all processed food in the country.
The Egyptian economy is dominated by mining (including oil, petroleum, and petroleum processing) and private services (including tourism and Suez Canal services). Mining does not, however, generate much employment, and most nonfarm workers in the country are employed in private and public services and construction. Incomes in many of these nonfarm sectors are only slightly higher than those in agriculture, due in part to low education levels and shortage of skilled labor in the country. Indeed, 85% of skilled-labor income is generated in the public sector. Energy is a small sector and renewable energy is still in its infancy, making up only a tiny share of total value added and employment in 2008.

4.2. Renewable Energy Scenarios

We assess the Egyptian renewable energy strategy in several scenarios (Table 5). All scenarios incorporate Egypt’s investment and production plans for renewable electricity production by 2020, both for specific technologies (labeled PV, CSP, and WIND) or for the combined investment into all technologies (labeled COMB). For combined scenarios, this involves a permanent 34% increase in FDI inflow to the renewable energy sector. This increase is equivalent to just under 1% of baseline GDP and 5% of baseline investment but total investment in renewables reaches 10% of total investment in 2020.
In all scenarios, we assume that all renewable electricity is exported while additional domestic demand for electricity is satisfied by domestic and import supply of conventional electricity, which is a perfect substitute to renewable sources. COMB1 (and PV, CSP, and WIND) examines a scenario without climate policy, where renewable electricity can only be exported at prices of conventional electricity. Given low fossil fuels prices, this requires substantial subsidies to CSP technology and to a less extent to PV technology (Table 5). COMB2 assumes that climate change mitigation policies raise conventional electricity prices to a level that covers CSP production costs. Finally, COMB3 assumes that, additionally, the Egyptian government reduces fuel subsidies by 10% as a complimentary measure to renewables policy. Consequent changes in the domestic budget balance, which follows from climate change mitigation policy and fuel policy balance, are accommodated through adjustments in investment, thus implying a redistribution of income from fuel consumers to investors.
Table 5. Scenarios for renewable energy development in Egypt by 2020.
Table 5. Scenarios for renewable energy development in Egypt by 2020.
ScenarioCapacity build-up, MWTotal FDI/baseline investment, %Reference electricity priceSubsidy rate, %
COMB1585–84204.80fuel unit costPV: 18.8%; CSP 75.1%
PV15–2200.85fuel unit cost18.80%
CSP20–11002.22fuel unit cost75.10%
WIND550–72003.23fuel unit cost-
COMB2585–84204.80converges to CSO unit cost-
COMB3585–84204.80fuel excise subsidy: −10%
Source: Authors’ compilation.

4.3. Impacts on Economic Growth and Employment

The renewables simulations reflect the case, where FDI and land are allocated to the renewables sectors according to Egypt’s renewable energy strategy. This implies that the electricity generating capacity of PV will increase from 15 megawatts in 2008 to 220 megawatts in 2020 and that of CSP and WIND from 20 to 1100 megawatts and from 550 to 7200 megawatts, respectively. We assume that the solar and wind parks will be located on brown field sites or other sites, where there is no other valuable land use—meaning that renewable energy parks will not displace any agricultural land being cultivated.
In the scenario without climate policy (COMB1), the Egyptian economy adopts low fossil fuel prices that require substantial subsidies to the renewable electricity sector, especially CSP electricity production, in order for them to be competitive with conventional energy. Our results show that total subsidies for PV and CSP increase gradually to up to 2.5% of GDP. Compared to the baseline scenario without renewable investment, the transition to a decarbonized power sector in Egypt leads to real income gains in the renewable energy sector as a result of FDI inflow to the renewable energy sector. However, these real income gains are dampened by a decrease in domestic fixed investment (see Table 6) and real income losses in other sectors and the overall impact of the renewable energy strategy on growth across the Egyptian economy for that scenario would be quite low; overall growth would be just 0.01 percentage points above baseline growth (see Table 6). The reduction of domestic fixed investment is mostly felt in the construction sector, where the growth rate is one percentage point lower than in the baseline and largely results from the subsidies to CSP technology (see column 4 in Table 7), while the impact of subsidies to PV technology is quite low, given PV’s small share in the renewable energy investment plan.
Table 6. Core macroeconomic assumptions and results, 2008–2020.
Table 6. Core macroeconomic assumptions and results, 2008–2020.
Initial, 2008Baseline scenarioInvestment in renewable energy sectors
COMB1PVCSPWINDCOMB2COMB3
Average annual growth rate, 2008–2020 (%)
Population80 millions2.002.002.002.002.002.002.00
Total GDP100.004.154.164.153.964.344.484.55
Fixed investment19.014.443.304.423.204.534.474.79
Labor24.932.002.002.002.002.002.002.00
Primary9.172.002.002.002.002.002.002.00
Secondary4.552.002.002.002.002.002.002.00
Tertiary11.212.002.002.002.002.002.002.00
Domestic capital stock73.792.952.872.952.872.962.963.03
Renewables FDI supply0.200.0034.213.3523.8627.1834.2134.21
Total land supply1.080.000.150.000.000.140.150.15
Final-year value, 2020
Electricity generating capacity, MW
PV1515220220 220220
CSP20201100 1100 11001100
Wind5505507200 720072007200
Real exchange rate100.00100.60100.20100.60101.2099.7099.0099.00
Nominal exchange rate100.00100.4099.90100.40100.6099.7099.2099.20
Domestic prices100.0099.8099.6099.8099.40100.00100.10100.10
Renewables FDI supply244.1 millions EUR244.134627.47102.221864.262660.994627.474627.47
Source: Results from the Egypt DCGE model.
Our findings suggest that, in the case of Egypt, the massive scaling up of renewable energy may negatively affect other sectors in two key ways. First, the expansion of PV and especially CSP technologies and the accompanying rise in subsidy payments to these sectors imply that an increasing amount of investment is drawn from the overall macroeconomic investment budget. Thus demand for investment goods is reduced, and this is mostly felt in the construction sector. Second, export sectors are negatively affected through Dutch disease effects, if all renewable energy is exported (see Table 7). This is because in our simulations the renewable energy sector eventually accounts for almost 25% of total merchandise export earnings by 2020. Since we assume that the current account balance is fixed in foreign currency, the increase in exports causes the real exchange rate to appreciate relative to the baseline scenario (see Table 6). This reduces the competitiveness of traditional export sectors, such as textiles, chemicals, electrical and nonelectrical machinery, and private services (tourism and Suez Canal services); exports and production of these sectors therefore declines.
Table 7. Sector growth results, 2008–2020.
Table 7. Sector growth results, 2008–2020.
GDP share 2008 (%)Baseline growth (%)Deviation from baseline scenario growth rate (%-point)
Investment in renewable energy sectors
COMB1PVCSPWINDCOMB2COMB3
GDP100.004.180.010.00−0.190.190.220.29
Agriculture13.412.87−0.040.00−0.02−0.01−0.020.04
Industry36.954.620.690.020.200.480.840.88
Mining15.834.82−0.090.00−0.08−0.01−0.010.05
Manufacturing14.924.511.610.030.700.921.621.59
Food processing3.614.18−0.040.00−0.03−0.02−0.030.03
Non-food manufacturing11.314.612.080.050.921.202.092.04
Renewable equipment manufacturing0.181.5434.923.3924.8527.4034.8534.82
PV manufacturing0.011.5431.2631.280.06−0.0831.1531.12
CSP manufacturing0.031.5350.050.0050.15−0.0749.9349.89
Wind manufacturing0.151.5429.760.000.0729.6829.7229.70
Textiles2.224.62−0.050.00−0.01−0.04−0.070.00
Wood1.204.61−0.070.00−0.04−0.03−0.060.02
Paper and printing0.414.620.020.000.030.00−0.010.04
Chemicals1.334.67−0.030.000.02−0.05−0.07−0.06
Rubber and plastics0.224.700.170.010.060.110.160.23
Petroleum and petroleum processing2.054.77−0.110.00−0.08−0.03−0.06−0.57
Non-metallic products0.864.630.020.00−0.030.040.110.08
Basic metals0.884.690.380.010.050.320.390.26
Fabricated metal products0.864.480.170.00−0.100.260.340.44
Non-electrical machinery0.264.70−0.220.00−0.09−0.13−0.19−0.12
Electrical machinery0.554.67−0.160.00−0.06−0.10−0.15−0.07
Transport equipment0.304.59−0.04−0.01−0.110.060.010.11
Utilities1.714.193.300.091.392.053.243.08
Electricity1.334.164.000.121.712.523.973.86
Renewable electricity0.041.6134.323.7023.0527.7734.2134.18
PV electricity0.001.5631.3031.280.04−0.0331.1531.12
CSP electricity0.011.5950.090.0050.12−0.0249.9349.89
Wind electricity0.041.6229.800.000.0129.7929.7229.70
Conventional1.294.240.220.000.080.140.230.08
Water0.384.300.470.000.220.260.29−0.11
Construction4.504.45−0.95−0.02−1.020.060.100.39
Services49.644.18−0.030.000.00−0.02−0.030.02
Private services18.354.41−0.040.000.00−0.04−0.060.00
Public services31.294.04−0.010.000.00−0.01−0.010.03
Notes: Sector summaries and averages in bold type. Source: Results from the Egypt DCGE model.
In the isolated PV and CSP scenarios, the demand effects clearly dominate. For example, the number of workers employed in construction falls by 438,000 and 6000 workers in the CSP and PV scenarios, respectively (see Table 8). By contrast, the number of workers used in construction increases by 21,000 in the WIND scenario, because the expansion of wind energy does not require additional subsidies and therefore does not lead to a crowding-out of domestic fixed investment. Moreover, workers are reallocated from trade-oriented agriculture and private services to the renewable energy sectors as a result of the real appreciation. In the COMB1 scenario, which replicates Egypt’s renewable energy strategy, both effects are at work and lead to a restructuring of the economy toward manufacturing and services while the construction sector contracts.
Table 8. Employment results, 2008–2020 (000 workers).
Table 8. Employment results, 2008–2020 (000 workers).
Employment, 2008Baseline employment, 2020Deviation from baseline scenario, final employmentEmployment generation/additional 100 MW electricity
Investment in renewable energy sectors
COMB1PVCSPWINDCOMB2COMB3PVCSPWIND
Total workers21,67726,422000000
Agriculture6897814553−1115−58−103−117−45210,615−878
Industry47806013−1593−3041352262601238−28,1502030
Mining3546001−1−1−1−1048−9
Manufacturing238729982338122103172141384511,2971547
Food processing4495174010−5−8−10−49900−74
Other manufacturing193924812298112108181151389310,3961621
Renewable equipment manufacturing1111185874103183182376768141549
PV manufacturing11880077377110
CSP manufacturing11710730706906793−1
Wind manufacturing9910600103106105−3201550
Textiles4305503010−7−13−13−80971−109
Wood232296004−3−6−6−49341−50
Paper and printing79101203−1−1−13264−8
Chemicals257331409−5−7−10−25840−75
Rubber and plastics43553021225119617
Petroleum and petroleum processing170222−400−4−6−23−71−26−54
Non-metallic products1662125031411131121
Basic metals1712212418151912285771233
Fabricated metal products166206110−1111516111−105172
Non-electrical machinery5065−200−2−3−3−38−14−31
Electrical machinery107137−301−4−6−5−2983−54
Transport equipment587400−1100−43−5012
Utilities27634224112121862691103178
Electricity20325017088147225741124
Renewable energy production0050234414318439
PV electricity0000000014300
CSP electricity0020202201840
Wind electricity003003220139
Conventional energy203250120661038255685
Water739280444−14436254
Construction20812627−417−6−4382137114−2867−40,598314
Services10,00012,26397−2187−82−132−152−99417,269−1240
Private services4783598641−1112−65−107−115−72710,363−984
Government services5217627756−175−17−25−37−2676907−256
Notes: Sector summaries and averages in bold type. Source: Results from the Egypt DCGE model.
Scenarios COMB2 and COMB3 assume that prices for fossil fuels rise swiftly and steadily because of limits on CO2 emissions, thereby leading to a convergence of renewable and conventional electricity production costs. The reduced need to subsidize solar power implies that the Dutch disease effect dominates, reducing the competitiveness of traditional export sectors, such as textiles, chemicals, electrical and non-electrical machinery, and private services (tourism and Suez Canal services), and these sectors decline. Agricultural production and food processing decrease despite rising domestic income since the appreciation of the real exchange rate also reduces the competitiveness of domestic import-competing sectors. Ultimately, the trade-offs from renewable energy production are smaller than the gains from new investments in the renewable energy sector. As a result, national GDP growth rates increase in all renewable energy scenarios, though these increases vary depending on the volume of investment and whether the renewable energy strategy is somehow flanked by additional measures.
Scenario COMB3 assumes that the renewable energy strategy is supported by a 10% reduction of fuel subsidies. Lower fuel subsidies have no direct impact on the renewable energy sectors, but exhibit significant indirect effects: by raising input costs to almost all sectors, they lead to a higher real appreciation. Moreover, lower government subsidies imply a reduction of the public deficit and an increase in investment, both of which lead to higher growth in the COMB3 scenario compared to COMB1 and COMB2.
Generally, the more profitable the renewable electricity production technology is, the larger its impact on national economic growth. Thus, the scenario with the largest positive gains in total GDP is WIND, which is the most profitable renewable electricity technology (see Table 2).
Table 8 reports impacts on employment. The number of jobs created in the renewable energy sector varies greatly across scenarios. The last three columns show the labor requirements to build up and operate a 100 megawatt solar or wind park. Generally, CSP is the most labor-intensive technology followed by PV and WIND. For all technologies, the number of workers used to produce renewable electricity is much smaller than the number of workers used to build up a renewable energy park. For example, one individual operation and maintenance worker in electricity production is needed for every 26 equipment manufacturing workers in the PV sector. The labor intensity of renewable electricity production is higher. Finally, CSP generation is also highly labor-intensive. In fact, the large amount of capital required to produce CSP equipment makes it the most labor-intensive option overall.
Low investments in PV and low labor-intensity mean that only 7700 manufacturing jobs are created in the PV scenario. Conversely, CSP equipment manufacturing employs 74,000 additional workers to produce renewable equipment in the CSP scenario. Wind equipment manufacturing is less labor-intensive than CSP and PV, however; the significant investment pays off and generates the most jobs.
Renewable electricity generation creates relatively few jobs, with almost all employment effects from renewable investment coming from equipment manufacturing. Moreover, unlike those in equipment manufacturing, jobs in electricity plants are largely reserved for semi-skilled and skilled workers; most of these workers must be sourced from other manufacturing subsectors as the renewable electricity sector grows. Lower skilled laborers mainly come from agriculture and services. Enhancing a renewable electricity industry in Egypt will therefore create new job opportunities for some sectors but will also impose significant adjustment costs on others, especially those in export agriculture and services.

4.4. Impacts on Household Incomes and Poverty

Investments in renewables increase national GDP and factor returns, causing household incomes to rise. Although this is true in all renewables scenarios, there are significant differences in the distributional impacts across household groups. Table 9 reports changes in households’ equivalent variation, which is a welfare measure that controls for changes in prices. All rural quintiles benefit from the expansion of renewable energy production in Egypt. What is more, lower-income households actually see the most benefit because they receive a larger share of their income from labor, which has become relatively scarce as a result of the renewables expansion.
Table 9. Household per capita equivalent variation results, 2008–2020.
Table 9. Household per capita equivalent variation results, 2008–2020.
Per-capita consumption, 2008 (LE)Baseline growth (%)Deviation from baseline scenario growth rate (%-point)
COMB1PVCSPWINDCOMB2COMB3
Rural2879.2
Quintile 12207.52.020.030.00−0.110.140.270.32
Quintile 22443.12.510.060.00−0.120.180.330.39
Quintile 32648.42.530.000.00−0.120.120.230.27
Quintile 42925.32.73−0.030.00−0.130.100.180.21
Quintile 53591.02.77−0.040.00−0.120.080.140.17
Urban4715.3
Quintile 12778.92.13−0.040.00−0.120.080.140.17
Quintile 23144.22.47−0.040.00−0.110.070.120.14
Quintile 33701.62.59−0.050.00−0.120.070.140.16
Quintile 44496.12.69−0.040.00−0.120.080.140.16
Quintile 58356.42.76−0.060.00−0.110.050.100.11
Source: Results from the Egypt DCGE model.
Urban households also benefit from an increase in the economy-wide returns to labor and capital and from the higher overall level of economic growth in the country. It is typically the middle of the urban income distribution that benefits the most, owing to the fact that these quintiles rely more heavily on labor wages for their incomes. Moreover, these households are typically endowed with semi-skilled and high-skilled labor, which is used fairly intensively in the renewable equipment manufacturing sectors (for example, as operators and technicians).
Figure 2 shows the national distributional effects of the renewables strategy on households’ equivalent variation. PV receives only a tiny share of the total investment volume of Egypt’s renewable strategy and therefore generates very little additional value added in the economy, so its effects on household welfare are small. CSP and WIND are far more beneficial for households. Moreover, the welfare gains are evenly distributed across lower expenditure quintiles. Clearly, only if the renewables strategy is combined with a reduction of fuel subsidies will the strategy lead to significant improvements in income distribution. Lower-income households benefit the most from the expansion of overall activity in COMB3.
Figure 2. Change in per capita equivalent variation from baseline scenario by quintile, 2010–2020. Notes: Equivalent variation is a measure of household welfare that controls for changes in commodity prices. Source: Results from the Egypt DCGE model.
Figure 2. Change in per capita equivalent variation from baseline scenario by quintile, 2010–2020. Notes: Equivalent variation is a measure of household welfare that controls for changes in commodity prices. Source: Results from the Egypt DCGE model.
Sustainability 07 07714 g002
Table 10 reports changes in national and regional poverty rates for the various renewable scenarios. The headcount rate—which measures the share of the population below the poverty line—declines most under the renewable energy cum fuel sector liberalization scenario (COMB3). There is almost no poverty reduction, however, in the unilateral Egyptian renewables strategy (COMB1). Yet, if undertaken within a global climate protection system (COMB2) and combined with a reduction of fuel subsidies (COMB3), prices for conventional electricity and higher public investment in Egypt will benefit poor households, which earn most of their income from the provision of low-skilled labor to construction and the production of consumer nondurables, including food and agricultural products.
Table 10. Poverty results, 2008–2020.
Table 10. Poverty results, 2008–2020.
Poverty rate, 2008 (%)Baseline poverty, 2020 (%)Deviation from final baseline scenario poverty rate (%age point)
COMB1PVCSPWINDCOMB2COMB3
Headcount (P0)21.812.20.00.00.3−0.3−0.5−0.7
Rural29.917.1−0.10.00.3−0.5−0.9−1.1
Urban10.45.30.10.00.2−0.1−0.1−0.2
Gap (P1)4.52.30.00.00.1−0.1−0.2−0.2
Rural6.23.20.00.00.1−0.1−0.3−0.3
Urban2.01.00.00.00.00.0−0.1−0.1
Squared gap (P2)1.40.70.00.00.0−0.1−0.1−0.1
Rural2.00.90.00.00.10.0−0.1−0.1
Urban0.60.30.00.00.00.00.00.0
Source: Results from the Egypt DCGE and microsimulation model.

5. Conclusions

Investments in renewable energy can be beneficial for economic growth, employment, and the poor. However, the quantity and quality of those benefits depend on the natural conditions, opportunity costs of conventional energy, structure of the economy, institutional capacity to implement energy sector reform, and other factors.
One of the countries that have significant potential for renewable energy production and ambitious plans for expansion is Egypt. While the recent political transition has put many initiatives on hold, the authors suggest that, under certain conditions, fostering the renewable energy strategy may be a promising way to provide an urgently needed impetus for the ailing economy. More specifically, the evidence-based results of our research lend themselves to the following recommendations.
  • Egypt should focus on the generation of wind power. Not only is wind power the sole renewable energy source competitive without subsidies, but it is also among the most favorable for economic growth, employment, and poverty reduction.
  • An export-led renewable energy strategy can offset some of the positive effects through Dutch disease. Results suggest that if all renewable energy planned under the Egyptian strategy is exported, these may compose up to 20% of all exports by 2020. Given the related appreciation of the real exchange rate and potential loss of jobs in other export sectors, it is advisable to consume a significant amount of additional energy domestically.
  • The implementation of the renewables strategy should be accompanied by a reduction of energy subsidies. Energy subsidies distort markets and render most of the renewable energies uncompetitive; they also contribute to Egypt’s high budget deficit. Reducing energy subsidies would not only lower the deficit but also support the development of renewable energies.
  • While investments in renewable energy have positive growth and employment effects, their impact on the poor has been rather modest to date. Thus, if poverty reduction is the main policy goal, other policies that support broader-based growth and targeted social safety nets are more appropriate.
Finally, it is important to stress that the implementation of a renewable energy strategy can be very challenging and complex. For example, windmills and solar panels designed for a European climate may not function well in Egypt’s desert region, where temperatures are higher and the volume of sand is a concern. If these potential caveats are carefully assessed, however, sun and wind have the potential to support economic development. Sound institutions, appropriate and lasting regulations, careful technology transfer, and cross-ministerial coordination are the keys to success.

Acknowledgments

Work on this paper was supported by PEGNet’s (Poverty Reduction, Equity and Growth Network) research exchange program with financial support from the German Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development. We would like to thank the Economic Research Forum (ERF) and the Central Agency for Pubic Mobilization and Statistics (CAPMAS) for the provision of the Household Income, Expenditure and Consumption Survey, HIECS (2008/2009) and the supply and use tables for 2008/2009. We also thank participants of the ERF 20th Annual Conference on Economic Development and Social Justice (22–24 March 2014 in Cairo), Nicolas Kreibich, and other participants of the DIE/PEGNet workshop on “Green and Social: Managing Synergies and Trade-offs” (12–14 March 2014 in Bonn), as well as two anonymous reviewers of the journal for their valuable comments.

Author Contributions

All authors contributed equally to this work. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Appendix

Appendix A1: DCGE Model Variables and Parameters

Index subscripts
iSectors and productshHouseholds
fFactorstTime periods
Endogenous variables (* denotes fixed by closure)
ARAverage economywide capital rental ratePMImport price
CHousehold consumption quantityPPProducer price
CPIConsumer price index *PSSupply price (without transaction costs)
DDomestic production supplied to local marketPTTotal domestic supply price (all regions)
EExport quantityPVValue-added price
ERNominal exchange rateQComposite commodity supply (with imports)
FBRecurrent fiscal balanceRGovernment tax revenues
FSForeign savings (capital inflows) *SKSectoral allocation of new capital
GGovernment consumption quantity *SPSectoral profit share
ITotal investment spendingSRSectoral return on capital
LTransaction cost demand quantityTTotal domestic supply quantity (all regions)
MImport quantityVFactor demand
PMarket priceVSTotal factor supply *
PDDomestic price (with transaction costs)XGross output (by region)
PEExport priceYTotal household income
PKCapital priceZWage distortion term
Exogenous variables
cdMarketing margin on domestic productsΓExport function shift parameter
ceMarketing margin on exportsΛProduction function shift parameter
cmMarketing margin on importsΦRegion aggregation function shift parameter
dEconomywide capital depreciation rateΩImport function shift parameter
ggGovernment consumption growth rateαProduction function share parameter
gpTotal factor productivity growth rateβHousehold marginal budget share
gvTotal factor supply growth rateγNon-income-related consumption quantity
hwHousehold foreign transfer receiptsδFactor income distribution shares
ioInput coefficient matrixεInvestment demand value shares
pweWorld export priceθImport substitution elasticity transformation
pwmWorld import priceκConsumer price index weights
rwGovernment foreign transfer receiptsμImport function share parameter
sMarginal savings ratesνRegion substitution elasticity transformation
tcCommodity sales tax rateρFactor substitution elasticity transformation
teExport tax rateτExport function share parameter
tfFactor tax rate (e.g., corporate tax)φExport substitution elasticity transformation
tmImport tariff rateψRegion aggregation function share parameter
tyDirect income tax rateωNew investment mobility parameter

Appendix A2. DCGE Model Equations.

P M i t = E R t ( 1 + t m i ) p w m i + i P i t c m i i
P E i t = E R t ( 1 t e i ) p w e i + i P i t c e i i
( 1 t c i ) P i t Q i t = P D i t D i t + P M i t M i t
P D i t = P S i t + i P i t c d i i
P T i t T i t = P S i t D i t + P E i t E i t
P P i r t = P V i r t + i P i t i o i i r
X i r t = Λ i r t ( f α i r f V i r f t ρ i r ) 1 / ρ i r
V i r f t = Λ i r t ρ i 1 + ρ i r X i r t ( α i f P V i r t Z i r f t W f t ) 1 / ( 1 + ρ i r )
T i t = Φ i t ( r ψ i f X i r t ν i ) 1 / ν i
X i r t = Φ i t ν i 1 + ν i T i t ( ψ i f P T i t P P i r t ) 1 / ( 1 + ν i )
T i t = Γ i [ τ i D i t φ i + ( 1 + τ i ) E i t φ i ] 1 / φ i
D i t E i t = ( τ i 1 τ i P D i t P E i t ) 1 / ( φ i 1 )
Q i t = Ω i [ μ i D i t θ i + ( 1 + μ i ) M i t θ i ] 1 / θ i
D i t M i t = ( μ i 1 μ i P M i t P D i t ) 1 / ( 1 + θ i )
L i t = i ( c d i i D i t + c e i i E i t + c m i i M i t )
Y h t = i r f δ h f ( 1 t f f ) Z i r f t W f t V i r f t + h w h E R t
C h i = β h i [ ( 1 s h t y h ) Y h t i P i γ h i ] P i 1 + γ h i
R t = i ( t c i P i t Q i t + t m i p w m i M i t + t e i p w e i E i t ) + h t y h Y h t + i r f t f f Z i r f t W f t V i r f t
R t + E R t r w = i P i t G i t + F B t
I t = h s h Y h t + F B t + E R t F S
I t ε i = P i t N i t
i r V i r f t = V S f t
Q i t = h C i h t + N i t + G i t + i i o i i X i t + L i t
F S ¯ + h h w h + r w = i p w m i M i t i p w e i E i t
C P I = i P i t κ i
V S f t + 1 = V S f t ( 1 + g v f t )             where   f k
Λ i t + 1 = Λ i t ( 1 + g p i t )
G i t + 1 = G i t ( 1 + g g i t )
V i r k t + 1 = ( 1 d ) V i r k t + S K i r k t I t P K t             where   P K t = i P i t ε i
S K i r k t = S P i r k t + ω S P i r k t ( S R i r k t A R t A R t )
S P i r k t = Z i r k t W k t V i r k t ( i r k Z i r k t W k t V i r k t ) 1
A R t = ( i r k Z i r k t W k t V i r k t ) ( i r k V i r k t ) 1
S R i r k t = Z i r k t W k t A R t
Source: [35].

Appendix B. Macro SAM for Egypt 2008/2009 (billions £E)

ActivitiesCommoditiesFactorsHouseholdsGovernmentRest of the worldSavings-InvestmentDirect taxesImport tariffsIndirect taxesTotal
Activities 1820.8 1820.8
Commodities751.5 821.498.0299.8200.0 2170.6
Factors1069.4 1069.4
Households 1067.5 42.042.3 1151.7
Government 3.4 141.314.1−30.9127.9
Rest of the world 366.61.9 368.5
Savings-Investment 189.0−12.023.0 200.0
Direct taxes 141.3 141.3
Import tariffs 14.1 14.1
Indirect taxes −30.9 −30.9
Total1820.82170.61069.41151.7127.9368.5200.0141.314.1−30.9
Source: Results from the Egypt DCGE model.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References and Notes

  1. International Energy Agency. CO2 Emissions from Fuel Combustion: Highlights 2012; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, International Energy Agency: Paris, France, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  2. International Energy Agency. Energy Technology Perspectives 2012: Pathways to a Clean Energy System; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, International Energy Agency: Paris, France, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  3. This led to the occurrence, for the first time in history, of developing countries surpassing transition and industrialized countries in aggregate CO2 emissions from the energy sector [1]. The net installations (that is, annual new power capacity installations without repowering) have been slightly larger for renewable energy technologies (RET) compared to conventional technology at the end of 2012.
  4. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Special Report on Renewable Energy Sources and Climate Change Mitigation; Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change: Cambridge, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  5. The global energy supply has not become significantly cleaner in the last two decades, as evidenced by the fact that the amount of CO2 emitted for each unit of energy supplied has decreased by less than 1 percent since 1990. Coal-fired power generation rose by nearly 6 percent between 2010 and 2012 globally and continues to grow faster than non-fossil energy sources on an absolute basis.
  6. Chow, J.; Kopp, R.J.; Portney, P.R. Energy Resources and Global Development. Science 2003, 203, 1528–1531. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  7. Jakob, M.; Haller, M.; Marschinski, R. Will History Repeat Itself? Economic Convergence and Convergence in Energy Use Patterns. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, 95–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Global Energy Assessment. Towards a Sustainable Future; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK; New York, NY, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  9. Popp, D.; Hascic, I.; Medhi, N. Technology and the Diffusion of Renewable Energy. Energy Econ. 2011, 33, 648–662. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Watson, J.; Sauter, R. Sustainable Innovation through Leapfrogging: A Review of Evidence. Int. J. Technol. Glob. 2011, 5, 170–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Rutovitz, J.; Atherton, A. Energy Sector Jobs to 2030: A Global Analysis. 2009. Available online: http://www.greenpeace.org/brasil/PageFiles/3751/energy-sector-jobs-to-2030.pdf (accessed on 12 June 2014).
  12. REN21, Renewables 2013 Global Status Report; Renewable Energy Policy Network for the 21st Century (REN21) Secretariat: Paris, France, 2013; Available online: http://www.ren21.net/Portals/0/documents/Resources/GSR/2013/GSR2013_lowres.pdf (accessed on 5 June 2014).
  13. International Energy Agency. Tracking Clean Energy Progress 2013: IEA Input to the Clean Energy Ministerial; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, International Energy Agency: Paris, France, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  14. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Optimising Investment Incentives for Renewable Energy Projects in MENA: A Stocktaking Report; MENA-OECD Task Force on Energy and Infrastructure, Working Paper; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development: Paris, France, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  15. African Development Bank. African Economic Outlook: Egypt; African Development Bank: Tunis, Tunisia, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  16. Breisinger, C.; Al-Riffai, P.; Ecker, O.; Abuismail, R.; Waite, J.; Abdelwahab, N.; Zohery, A.; El-Laithy, H.; Armanious, D. Tackling Egypt’s Rising Food Insecurity in Times of Transition; Joint Country Policy Note; World Food Programme, Country Office Arab Republic of Egypt, and International Food Policy Research Institute: Washington, DC, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  17. A large share of poor and nonpoor people clusters around the poverty line, which can partially explain the rapid rate of increase of people moving into poverty in recent years.
  18. US Energy Information Administration. Egypt: Overview; US Energy Information Administration: Washington, DC, USA, 2013.
  19. Regional Center for Renewable Energy and Energy Efficiency. Egypt Renewable Energy Country Profile; Regional Center for Renewable Energy and Energy Efficiency: Cairo, Egypt, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  20. African Development Bank. Clean Energy Development in Egypt; African Development Bank: Tunis, Tunisia, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  21. Ibrahim, A. Renewable Energy Sources in the Egyptian Electricity Market: A Review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2012, 16, 2016–2030. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Desertec Industrial Initiative. Economic Impacts of Desert Power; Desertec Industrial Initiative: Munich, Germany, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  23. The development of wind technology was initiated in 1996 when the New & Renewable Energy Authority (NREA) was formed. A series of large-scale grid-connected wind projects have been implemented with a total installed capacity of about 550 megawatts in 2010 [20].
  24. Vidican, G. Building Domestic Capabilities in Renewable Energy. A Case Study of Egypt; Deutsches Institut für Entwicklungspolitik: Bonn, Germany, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  25. Amer, H. Renewable Energy Strategy for 2020 and Regulatory Framework. Egyptian Electric Regulatory and Consumer Protection Agency. In Proceedings of the Global Workshop on Grid Connected Renewable Energy, Washington, DC, USA, 31 August–4 September 2009.
  26. The Desertec vision aims to generate sustainable power from the sites where renewable sources of energy are most abundant and export it to regions like Europe with high electricity demand. This also contributes to combatting climate change, ensuring a reliable energy supply, and promoting security and development. Available online: http://www.desertec.org (accessed on 10 May 2014).
  27. Fragkos, P.; Kouvaritakis, N.; Capros, P. Prospects for Energy Supply and Demand in the Southern Mediterranean, MEDPRO Technical Report No. 22 (interim version); CEPS: Brussels, Belgium, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  28. Haller, M.; Ludig, S.; Bauer, N. Decarbonization scenarios for the EU and MENA power system: Considering spatial distribution and short term dynamics of renewable generation. Energy Policy 2012, 47, 282–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Massetti, E.; Ricci, E.C. An assessment of the optimal timing and size of investments in concentrated solar power. Energy Econ. 2013, 38, 186–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. An aggregated macro-SAM can be found in Appendix B. For the detailed SAM, please contact the authors.
  31. Central Agency for Public Mobilization and Statistics. Household Income, Expenditure and Consumption Survey, HIECS (2008/2009). Version 1.0 of the Licensed Data Files, Provided by the Economic Research Forum. Available online: http//www.erfdataportal.com/index.php/catalog (accessed on 20 November 2013).
  32. International Labour Organisation. Key Indicators of the Labour Market (KILM 8). International Labour Organisation. Available online: http//www.ilo.org/empelm/what/WCMS_114240/lang--en/index.htm (accessed on 12 February 2014).
  33. Central Agency of Public Mobilization and Statistics. Supply and Use Tables for 2008/2009; Central Agency of Public Mobilization and Statistics: Cairo, Egypt, 2013.
  34. Calzadilla, A.; Wiebelt, M.; Blohmke, J.; Klepper, G. Desert Power 2050: Regional and Sectoral Impacts of Renewable Electricity Production in Europe, the Middle East, and North Africa; Kiel Working Paper 1891; Kiel Institute for the World Economy: Kiel, Germany, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  35. Diao, X.; Thurlow, J. A Recursive Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Model. In Strategies and Priorities for African Agriculture: Economy-wide Perspectives from Country Studies; Diao, X., Thurlow, J., Benin, S., Fan, S., Eds.; International Food Policy Research Institute: Washington, DC, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Al-Riffai, P.; Blohmke, J.; Breisinger, C.; Wiebelt, M. Harnessing the Sun and Wind for Economic Development? An Economy-Wide Assessment for Egypt. Sustainability 2015, 7, 7714-7740. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su7067714

AMA Style

Al-Riffai P, Blohmke J, Breisinger C, Wiebelt M. Harnessing the Sun and Wind for Economic Development? An Economy-Wide Assessment for Egypt. Sustainability. 2015; 7(6):7714-7740. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su7067714

Chicago/Turabian Style

Al-Riffai, Perrihan, Julian Blohmke, Clemens Breisinger, and Manfred Wiebelt. 2015. "Harnessing the Sun and Wind for Economic Development? An Economy-Wide Assessment for Egypt" Sustainability 7, no. 6: 7714-7740. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su7067714

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop