Next Article in Journal
The Effect of Payments for Ecosystem Services Programs on the Relationship of Livelihood Capital and Livelihood Strategy among Rural Communities in Northwestern China
Previous Article in Journal
Dependence of Parking Pricing on Land Use and Time of Day
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Factors Influencing Compensation Demanded for Environmental Impacts Generated by Different Economic Activities

by
Virna Vaneza Gutiérrez
1,2,*,
Luis Abdón Cifuentes
1,4 and
Nicolás C. Bronfman
3,4
1
Industrial and Systems Engineering Department, Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile, Vicuña Mackenna 4860, Santiago 7820436, Chile
2
Industrial Engineering School, Universidad Diego Portales, Vergara 432, Santiago 8370190, Chile
3
Engineering Sciences Department, Universidad Andres Bello, Av. República 252, Santiago 8370134, Chile
4
National Research Center for Integrated Natural Disaster Management, CONICYT/FONDAP/15110017, Santiago 7820436, Chile
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2015, 7(7), 9608-9627; https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su7079608
Submission received: 12 May 2015 / Revised: 27 June 2015 / Accepted: 5 July 2015 / Published: 17 July 2015
(This article belongs to the Section Economic and Business Aspects of Sustainability)

Abstract

:
This work advances the understanding of compensation demanded for environmental impacts on atmosphere, lakes and rivers, soil, and ocean generated by mining, urban, fishing and agriculture activities. Our aims are to determine whether compensation demanded depends on the standard variables used in the field of risk perception (as perceived risk, public acceptability and trust in regulating authorities), and to explore whether these relationships depend on the environment affected and on the economic activity generating the impacts. General Linear Models were used to analyze survey responses from 427 citizens of Santiago, Chile. Results showed that compensation demanded depends on perceived risk, acceptability, and on the economic activity, but not on the environment affected. Acceptability depends on trust in authorities, on perceived risk and on the economic activity. Perceived risk depends on trust, the economic activity and the environment affected. Overall, environmental impacts from the mining industry are perceived as riskier, less acceptable, and have a higher compensation demanded than those generated by the other sectors. These results suggest that to achieve sustainable development, regulations should consider not only environmental impacts but also the economic activity originating them.

1. Introduction

It is important for risk managers to understand how people think and react to different risks. Such an awareness not only allows the development of effective communication strategies, but also enables more informed decisions that lead to greater public acceptance [1]. Traditional risk analysis usually does not include the impacts that may result from subjective judgments of those affected, such as loss of trust in institutions, political and social pressure and opposition to projects, among others [1,2,3].
During the past three decades, many studies have indicated that social trust significantly influences public acceptance of various technologies [4,5,6,7]. Moreover, many researchers have shown that there is a relationship between social trust in regulatory entities and perceived risk [8,9,10].
Hence, perceived risk, public acceptability and social trust are closely linked [11,12]. There are models in which it is implicitly or explicitly assumed that social trust is a determining factor of public acceptability and risk perceptions [13,14]. These models postulate that the level of trust that people place in both private and public institutions determines the perceived risk, which in turn determines the degree of acceptability of activities or impacts.
Numerous studies have found associations between perceptions of risk, acceptability and trust in regulatory institutions of various hazardous substances and technologies, including food [6,14,15], energy [16,17,18], and industrial facilities [19,20,21], but little is known about these relations for environmental impacts [22] and even less is known whether the economic activity originating the impacts has an influence. This issue is important because: (1) Environmental risks can be perceived differently from technological risks that are extensively studied, because environmental hazards causes negative externalities and are not perceived with a direct benefit as technological hazards are; (2) it contributes to the understanding of public perception of environmental hazards derived from different economic activities; and (3) comparing across different economic activities may help authorities to customize their environmental policies and strategies considering the economic activity they belong.
The following introduces the concept of compensation that is demanded in order to accept the risk imposed on society by environmental hazards. We also briefly describe the Chilean economic context in which four main economic activities have marked the economic growth of the country.

1.1. Demanded Compensation

Environmental economics characterizes environmental hazards (atmospheric contamination, climate change, etc.) as public bad [23,24,25] because they do not directly reflect the activity or technology behind them, which are indeed perceived as beneficial. Given the nature of public bad, its value is different from that of a private good or bad [26,27,28], since its consumption or production generates externalities. In other words, it directly affects the well-being of unrelated third parties who did not choose to incur that cost or benefit [29].
Welfare economics suggests two ways to measure changes in consumers’ well being. First, willingness to pay (WTP) shows how much an individual would be willing to pay in order to obtain an improvement or benefit from an environmental change. Secondly, compensation demanded (CD) reflects what an individual would demand in order to accept an environmental change that would aggravate their situation. The choice between WTP or CD as a welfare change measure depends on the assumed property rights situation [30,31,32]. Hence, in the case where an individual believed he/she or the society has the property rights, it would be valid to ask how much society should be compensated for accepting the impacts on the environment from local projects.
A monetary compensation would increase the acceptability of unwanted local projects [33], but directly offering monetary compensation might generate what is known as “the bribe effect,” when people consider the risk-generating activity to be illegal and choose not to accept a compensation, regardless of the amount being offered [33]. One way of diminishing this effect is to ask for in-kind compensations (e.g., schools, parks, hospitals, reforestation) instead of monetary compensations [34].
With a strong base in both theory and method, Earle (2010) reviewed 133 studies that develop some trust model in the risk-management field. Of these, 33 include environmental hazards. Within these, 13 develop some model of trust and risk; four provide a model of acceptability and trust; two focused on a model of acceptability, risk and trust; one is related to trust, perceived risk and perceived benefit; and one relates all four variables [35]. From all the studies reviewed, none includes the concept of compensation demanded for environmental hazard. As investigation in environmental hazards and risk management is an essential research area, further research is needed to clarify the relationship between compensation demanded and the other variables.

1.2. Chilean Economic Context

According to the International Monetary Fund, the Chilean economy is the sixth largest economy in Latin America and the Caribbean [36] and it is ranked as the second best emerging economy worldwide [37]. Its main economic sector is services, followed by mining (mainly copper, of which it is the main world producer [38]). Chile’s export profile comprises approximately 58% mining, 34% industrial and 8% agricultural produce exports [39]. Chile also has a maritime economic exclusive zone that favors large commercial fishing activity.
However, as the country progresses, the population’s demands for control and regulation of environmental impacts and risks grows. There is increasing opposition to economic activities that affect the environment, such as the explosive urban development of the country’s main cities. On a regional level, 63% of the population is concentrated in three regions (Metropolitan Region, V and VII), with the former alone having more than 40% of the entire national population, thus exerting intense pressure on natural resources [40]. This urban growth has significantly affected the air quality in Santiago, thus adversely affecting the health of the population [41,42]. Another economic activity with greater opposition is mining. Large mining operations have generated a number of negative impacts on the environment [43,44]. These impacts have met with opposition from communities and stakeholders [45,46,47], thus making it more difficult to develop sustainable mining projects. We also find opposition to projects of agriculture mainly because the overexploitation of land and water conservation and use rights.
In this context, many companies in Chile have either voluntarily or mandatorily implemented a series of compensatory measures in order to offset the environmental impacts and their risks, and to achieve greater public acceptance for their projects [48,49,50,51,52,53]. Although these compensations have generally taken place within a well-defined regulatory framework [54,55,56], they do not guarantee the social acceptance of a project. It is necessary to consider other factors, such as the public opinion [57] and how much society trust institutions in charge of regulations [58,59,60,61].
This paper is organized as follows: Section 2 summarizes the aims of the study, proposed theoretical model and hypothesis. Section 3 explains the methodology, Section 4 the results, and finally we discuss the main implications of the results and highlight the conclusions of the study.

2. Aims and Hypothesis

The aim of this study is to analyze how demanded compensation to accept environmental impacts from different economic activities is influenced by the standard variables used in the field of risk perception research (as perceived risk, public acceptability and trust in authorities). To our knowledge, this is the first time that the dependence of compensation demanded with acceptability, perceived risk and social trust is analyzed. This research also contributes to the understanding of public perception of environmental hazards derived from different economic activities, providing important information to authorities and private sector to customize their environmental policies and strategies considering the economic activity they belong.
The conceptual model is shown in Figure 1. The direction and sign of these relationships are expressed in the following hypotheses:
H1:
Perceived risk depends negatively on trust in regulatory institutions. There is an effect upon this relationship of the economic activity and the affected environment.
H1:
Acceptability depends negatively on perceived risk and positively on social trust. There is an effect upon this relationship of the economic activity and the affected environment.
H1:
Compensation demanded depends negatively on public acceptability, positively on perceived risk and positively on trust in authorities. There is an effect upon this relationship of the economic activity and the affected environment.
Figure 1. Proposed theoretical model for compensation demanded, public acceptability, perceived risk and social trust. All the relationships are affected by the economic activity and the affected environment, not shown in the figure.
Figure 1. Proposed theoretical model for compensation demanded, public acceptability, perceived risk and social trust. All the relationships are affected by the economic activity and the affected environment, not shown in the figure.
Sustainability 07 09608 g001

3. Materials and Methods

3.1. Procedure and Participants

We used an online survey to poll a sample of the population of Santiago. A marketing agency implemented the survey and designed the sampling method in order to obtain participants with similar socio-demographic characteristic to those of the population of Santiago. An inclusion criterion was restricted to individuals aged 18 years or older. A one-time email invitation was sent to approximately 5000 people. The email contained an explanation of the study along with a link to the questionnaire. The survey was conducted in 2006.
A total of 427 people answered the online survey. The response rate was within the expected range of values assured by the agency for this type of application and the number of respondents was adequate for the required statistical analysis. Six participants were excluded because they did not answer several questions and were dropped at the beginning. The sample for the present study consisted of 421 participants (54% of whom were women), average age was 32 (SD = 1.8 years).
Participation in the study was voluntary and all information collected was treated as confidential in strict compliance with the norms pertaining to observational studies. All individuals gave their consent once they accessed the link provided in the e-mail invitation. Nevertheless, they could drop the survey at any time. The study was approved by Universidad Diego Portales’s Research Committee. In the stored data, respondents were only identified by a number.

3.2. Survey Instrument

The survey was designed according to the questionnaire used by Bronfman (2008) that was implemented to a sample of undergraduate students in 2003; that is, we took the social trust, perceived risk and public acceptability variables with their 7-point scales. We adapted them to fit our focus on environmental hazards and added a new question to measure demanded compensation, either in-kind or monetary. All questions were tested using a focus group of 10 lay people. The revised questions are detailed in Table 1.
Table 1. Study variables and measurement scales.
Table 1. Study variables and measurement scales.
ScaleQuestion DescriptionScale Points
(1)(7)
TrustHow much trust do you have for the entities in charge of regulating the hazards to which the national population is exposed as a result of (name of hazard)?Little TrustA Lot of Trust
Perceived RiskIn your opinion, to how much risk in general is the national population exposed as a result of (name of hazard)?LittleA Lot
AcceptabilityWe are inevitably exposed to various types of hazards that affect us in different forms and degrees. Given that, in your opinion, how acceptable is the risk to which the national population is currently exposed as a result of (name of hazard)?UnacceptableAcceptable
Compensation DemandedCompensation to society is a tool that can be applied, for example, in reforesting affected areas, cleaning and repairing aquifer resources, restoring degraded soil, monetary compensation to affected people, etc. In your opinion, how much should society be compensated in the case of (name of hazard)? LittleA Lot
Participants had to answer these 4 questions for each of 16 environmental hazards. Explicitly, these 16 environmental hazards reflected the impact of 4 main economic activities (mining, fishing industry, agriculture and urban activities) on 4 affected environments components (atmosphere, oceans, lakes and rivers and soil). Even though urban activities is not precisely an economic activity, the survey asked for environmental impacts due to mining activities, agriculture activities, fishing activities and urban activities. We decided to name these four sources of environmental impacts as economic activities just to make the comparison more appealing. We were interested in studying different environmental impacts caused by multiple economic activities gathered in cities with impacts from economic activities that are more likely to be situated outside cities such as fishing, mining and agricultural activities

3.3. Statistical Analysis

We wanted to test the different impacts of the economic activities and environment affected and to assess the relationship proposed in the theoretical model. Thus, to test the underlying hypothesis we used a General Linear Model (GLM) using the command Univariate GLM of IBM SPSS Version 21.0.
Y i j k = μ + α j + β k + β X i + ( α β ) j k + ε i j k
where:
  • μ = general mean
  • α j = μ j μ = environment effect (atmosphere, lakes and rivers, ocean and soil)
  • β k = μ k μ = economic activity effect (mining, fishing, agriculture and urban activities)
  • β X i = effect of the continuous variables (trust, perceived risk and acceptability)
  • ( α × β ) j k = interaction between environment affected and economic activity
  • ε i j k = error term
Before performing the GLM, the normality of errors and variables was tested. Given their asymmetry and kurtosis lower than |2.0| and |9.0|, respectively, we verified that these assumptions are met [62]. In addition, the homogeneity of variances was tested using Levene’s F test. The models’ homoscedasticity with dependent variables acceptability and trust fulfilled this assumption, F (15, 6656) = 0.660, p = 0.826; F (15, 6656) = 0.592, p = 0.884, respectively. Compensation demanded and perceived risk did not comply, but by having balanced samples and variances that do not differ by a ratio greater than 2:1, we were able to proceed with the analysis, given that these techniques are robust to slight violations of this assumption [63,64,65]. The statistical significance was set at the 0.05 level.

4. Results

4.1. Descriptive Statistics

Table 2 indicates the mean values and their standard deviation for the four study variables for each of the 16 environmental hazards, considering the responses from all participants.
Table 2. Mean (standard deviation) of study variables by economic activity and environment affected.
Table 2. Mean (standard deviation) of study variables by economic activity and environment affected.
Economic ActivityAffected environment (Hazard)CDPAPRTA
MiningAtmospheric pollution due to5.95 (1.41)2.47 (1.73)5.39 (1.40)2.07 (1.41)
Lakes and rivers polluted by5.95 (1.45)2.45 (1.71)5.30 (1.48)2.00 (1.40)
Soil pollution due to5.93 (1.42)2.55 (1.73)5.20 (1.50)2.01 (1.35)
Ocean pollution by5.93 (1.45)2.50 (1.78)5.22 (1.50)2.04 (1.36)
UrbanAtmospheric pollution due to5.85 (1.51)2.50 (1.78)5.72 (1.36)2.08 (1.42)
Lakes and rivers polluted by5.75 (1.52)2.60 (1.82)5.36 (1.40)2.12 (1.38)
Soil pollution due to5.69 (1.61)2.58 (1.81)5.28 (1.45)2.06 (1.33)
Ocean pollution by5.68 (1.54)2.58 (1.74)5.17 (1.42)2.13 (1.37)
Fishing Atmospheric pollution due to5.81 (1.47)2.67 (1.76)4.94 (1.51)2.15 (1.42)
Lakes and rivers polluted by5.75 (1.52)2.69 (1.81)4.98 (1.53)2.11 (1.42)
Soil pollution due to5.67 (1.55)2.70 (1.70)4.65 (1.68)2.03 (1.35)
Ocean pollution by5.67 (1.53)2.76 (1.71)4.63 (1.62)2.11 (1.38)
Agriculture Atmospheric pollution due to5.60 (1.50)2.85 (1.70)4.75 (1.53)2.14 (1.35)
Lakes and rivers polluted by5.60 (1.55)2.76 (1.75)4.71 (1.62)2.15 (1.36)
Soil pollution due to5.60 (1.54)2.78 (1.72)4.70 (1.71)2.08 (1.35)
Ocean pollution by5.59 (1.53)2.81 (1.74)4.87 (1.48)2.19 (1.42)
CD = Compensation demanded, PA = Public acceptability, PR = Perceived risk and TA = Trust in authorities; Data were sorted by CD in decreasing order within each economic activity.
Compensation demanded was high; none of the mean score is smaller than 5 on the 7-point scale. Public acceptability was low, as not even one mean has a level of acceptability over 3 points on the scale. Perceived risk could be considered high (its average varies from 4.63 to 5.72 points). Trust in authorities in charge of regulating the risks presents the lowest scores, with very small variations between hazards or economic sectors.
The mining sector has the greatest compensation demanded (M =5.94, SD = 1.43) and is the least accepted (M = 2.49, SD = 1.73). In terms of perceived risk, urban activities exhibit the greater perceived risk (M = 5.38, SD = 1.42).
The mean values for the affected environments (atmosphere, lakes and rivers, soils and ocean) in compensation demanded, acceptability and trust show no clear differences. Polluted rivers and lakes are perceived with the greatest risk (M = 5.14, SD = 1.46) and contaminated soils exhibit the least perceived risk (M = 4.94, SD =1.53).

4.2. The Influence of Social Trust on the Perception of Risks (H1)

The results show that trust in regulatory institutions does not depend on either the economic activity or the affected environment. In addition, there is no significant effect of the interaction between the environment affected and the economic activity.
The GLM indicated that there is no effect of the interactions between trust and the affected environment or the economic sector; as such, they were excluded from the model.
The final model found a negative and significant effect of trust over perceived risk (F (1, 6655) = 72.1, p < 0.05). Both main effects, economic activity (F (3, 6655) = 74.4, p < 0.05) and the affected environment (F (3, 6655) = 5.6, p < 0.05), turned out to be significant. The interaction between factors also proved to be significant (F (9, 6655) = 4.7, p < 0.05).
Figure 2 illustrates the marginal means of perceived risk according to economic activity and the environment affected while social trust remains fixed at its mean value of 2.09. This graph shows that mining and urban activities are the economic activities that are perceived as the riskiest. Once controlled by social trust, mining and urban activities are above the other economic activities on the mean values of perceived risk in all affected environments.
Figure 2. Estimated marginal means of perceived risk by economic activity and environment affected.
Figure 2. Estimated marginal means of perceived risk by economic activity and environment affected.
Sustainability 07 09608 g002
In order to understand the effect upon perceived risk of the economic activities or affected environments, it is necessary to consider the interaction term. That is, the effect of the economic activity also depends on the environment being affected by that activity and vice versa (see Table 3). Thus, for an equal level of trust, atmospheric pollution due to urban activities is perceived with the highest risk.
Table 3. General Linear Model (GLM) results predicting perceived risk from social trust, economic activity and environment affected.
Table 3. General Linear Model (GLM) results predicting perceived risk from social trust, economic activity and environment affected.
PredictorEstimateStd. Errortobsp(|t| > |tobs|)
(Intercept)5.5170.07970.20.000
continuous variable
Social Trust−0.1140.013−8.50.000
β k : Economic activity a
Mining−0.0610.104−0.590.556
Agriculture−0.5560.104−5.30.000
Fishing−0.2950.104−2.80.005
α j : Environment affected b
Atmosphere0.4390.1044.20.000
Lakes and rivers0.0860.1040.820.411
Soil−0.1080.104−1.00.298
( α × β ) j k : Interactions between environment affected and economic activity
Mining × Atmosphere−0.3660.147−2.50.013
Agriculture × Atmosphere−0.4640.147−3.20.002
Fishing × Atmosphere−0.7770.147−5.30.000
Mining × Lakes and rivers0.0860.1470.580.561
Agriculture × Lakes and rivers0.0720.1470.490.626
Fishing × Lakes and rivers−0.1200.147−0.820.414
Mining × Soil0.0860.1470.580.561
Agriculture × Soil0.1430.1470.970.330
Fishing × Soil−0.2390.147−1.60.105
Note: a: Urban activities as a base category; b: Ocean as a base category.

4.3. Acceptability and Its Relation to Perceived Risk and Trust in Authorities (H2)

The full GLM model showed that none of the interactions between perceived risk or social trust and the factors were significant; as such, they were eliminated from the final model (see Table 4).
The greater the perceived risk, the less it is accepted (F (1, 6663) = 249.5, p < 0.05). Meanwhile, trust in regulatory institutions turned out to be significant (F (1, 6663) = 359.5, p < 0.05), thus indicating that a greater trust corresponds to a greater acceptance of environmental risks. The model shows that the acceptability of an environmental risk depends on the economic activity that generates it (F (3, 6663) = 2.7, p < 0.05), but not on the environment that is affected (F(1, 6663) = 0.12, p = 0.95).
Figure 3 illustrates the marginal means of social acceptability by economic activity and environment affected, while social trust and perceived risk remain fixed at their mean values (2.09 and 5.06, respectively). It can be clearly appreciated that there is no interaction between factors, because all of the lines representing each economic activity are parallel. Agriculture and mining are the most and least accepted, respectively.
Figure 3. Estimated marginal means of public acceptability by economic activity and environment affected.
Figure 3. Estimated marginal means of public acceptability by economic activity and environment affected.
Sustainability 07 09608 g003
Table 4 presents the model’s estimates. For the same level of perceived risk and social trust, greater differences were found in agriculture vs. mining, with mining being the least accepted economic activity.
Table 4. GLM results predicting acceptability from perceived risk, social trust, economic activity and environment affected.
Table 4. GLM results predicting acceptability from perceived risk, social trust, economic activity and environment affected.
VariableEstimateStd. Errortobsp(|t| > |tobs|)
(Intercept)3.2010.09234.80.000
continuous variable
Perceived risk−0.2130.014−15.80.000
Trust in authorities0.2820.01519.00.000
β k : Economic activity a
Mining−0.1650.058−2.90.004
Urban−0.0910.058−1.60.119
Fishing−0.0720.058−1.30.210
α j : Environment affected b
Atmosphere−0.0030.058−0.060.955
Lakes and rivers0.0150.0580.260.793
Soil0.0270.0580.470.636
Note: a: Agriculture as a base category; b: Ocean as a base category

4.4. Demanded Compensation and Its Relation to Perceived Risk and Acceptability (H3)

In the full GLM model, the interactions between the affected environment, trust in authorities, acceptability and perceived risk were not significant. Neither was the interaction between trust in authorities, perceived risk and economic activity. In addition, there is no significant effect of the interaction between the environment affected and the economic activity. They were, thus, excluded from the final model (See Table 5).
The final model offers the following results: demanded compensation depends positively on perceived risk (F (1, 6659) = 897.8, p < 0.05), negatively on acceptability (F (1, 6660) = 211.6, p < 0.05) and trust in authorities (F (1, 6659) = 36.8, p < 0.05 . The model shows that there is a significant effect of the economic activity on demanded compensation (F (3, 6659) = 9.4, p < 0.05), but not of the affected environment (F (3, 6659) = 0.07, p = 0.98). There is an effect of the interaction between social acceptability and the economic activity (F (3, 6659) = 4.5, p < 0.05).
Figure 4 illustrates the marginal means of demanded compensation by economic activity and environment affected, with trust in authorities, public acceptability and perceived risk fixed at their mean values. It can be clearly observed that there is no effect of the interaction between factors and that mining is the activity with greater compensation demanded while urban activities being the least.
Figure 4. Estimated marginal means of demanded compensation by economic activity and environment affected.
Figure 4. Estimated marginal means of demanded compensation by economic activity and environment affected.
Sustainability 07 09608 g004
In order to interpret the effect of the economic sectors on demanded compensation, the interaction between acceptability and the economic activity must be considered. For example, by controlling for risk, trust and acceptability, mining, agriculture and fishing have a greater incremental effect than urban activities on compensation demanded, but, at the same time, this effect is diminished when the relation between economic activity and acceptability is considered (see Table 5). We can consider that both agriculture and fishing decrease the compensation by virtue of being the two most accepted activities. We can also state that the effect of acceptability on compensation demanded depends on the economic sector (slope effect). Therefore, this effect is greater for agriculture and fishing (greater negative slope). In general, mining is the activity that shows the greatest compensation demanded.
Table 5. GLM results predicting demanded compensation from trust in authorities, perceived risk, acceptability and economic activities.
Table 5. GLM results predicting demanded compensation from trust in authorities, perceived risk, acceptability and economic activities.
VariableEstimateStd. Errortobsp(|t| > |tobs|)
(Intercept)4.3280.09445.90.000
continuous variable
Perceived risk0.3360.01130.00.000
Acceptability−0.0940.019−5.00.000
Trust in authorities−0.0760.012−6.10.000
β k : Economic activity a
Mining0.3150.0823.80.000
Agriculture0.3310.0863.90.000
Fishing0.4120.0854.90.000
α j : Environment affected b
Atmosphere0.0010.0470.030.979
Lakes and rivers0.0050.0470.100.923
Soil0.0190.0470.410.681
( α × β ) j k : Interactions between environment affected and economic activity
Acceptability × Mining−0.0380.027−1.40.157
Acceptability ×Agriculture−0.0850.027−3.20.002
Acceptability × Fishing −0.0810.027−3.10.002
Note: a: Urban activities as a base category; b: Ocean as a base category.

5. Discussion and Conclusions

This research furthers the understanding of how demanded compensation for environmental impacts caused by some of the main economic activities is influenced by the public’s acceptability of the risks imposed to society, the risk itself and the trust in regulating authorities. Therefore, the findings will be discussed in two aspects: whether the relationships between variables exist and if those relationships are affected by the economic activity affected, the environment affected, or both.

5.1. Social Trust

Our results show that the population’s level of trust in regulators is low and independent of the economic activity that generates the environmental impacts or of the impacts itself. This result is a cause of concern that revealed the complexity and challenge for policy makers to gain trust within society.
A number of studies assessed the critical role of the population’s trust in regulatory institutions when it comes to implementing risk management policies [3,58,59]. Raising trust in Chilean regulatory institutions is neither trivial nor immediate. Some high visibility events occurred during the last decade that could have, in part, influenced this low level of trust in authorities. In 2004, the operations of Celco, a cellulose-processing plant, caused the death and massive migration of the black-necked swans from the natural reserve “Carlos Anwandter” [66]; the general population was strongly opposed to this type of project; they also expressed a significant level of mistrust in the government entities that were responsible. A similarly complex event that put into question the Chilean government was the approval of the Pascua-Lama mining project in 2006. This project's operation implied a threat to biodiversity and irreversible damages to the glaciers that supply water to that region [44]. The evaluation report on environmental management, which was elaborated upon by the OECD in 2005 [67], severely questioned the Chilean environmental regulatory institutions at that time. One of the most relevant aspects of the report was the recommendation for a stronger environmental institutionalism endowed with greater resources, as well as the need for a better enforcement capacity and more integration of environmental aspects in public policies. These antecedents could partly help to explain the population’s low trust in regulatory entities at the time of our study.
Bearing this in mind, it is crucial that regulatory entities seek effective ways of creating transparent and participative public policies. They should inform the public of the environmental risks of the various economic activities and, in this way, increase trust in regulatory entities [61]. Actually, the Chilean environmental law establishes diverse mechanisms whereby the population can obtain information and education on environmental issues. It also proposes mechanism so that people can demand their rights when their quality of life is being undermined [56]. Although this mechanism has improved over time, with a substantial rise in public consultation from the period before the law was passed to the present, the low level of public trust reflects that these efforts may have been insufficient [57].

5.2. The Influence of Social Trust on the Perception of Risks

Our results are consistent with the findings of others who have studied this relationship in a context of new technologies [8,9,68]; that is, where perceived risk is a consequence of trust placed in regulatory institutions. A novel result, however, is that perceived risk also depends on the economic activity that generates the impact and the environment affected. Even when controlling for trust, the environmental impacts of urban activities and mining are perceived with high risk. Regarding urban activities, it should be considered that the poll was applied to a Santiago sample and over 40% of the national population is concentrated in Santiago. The capital has experienced an accelerated growth over the past years. Between 1940 and 2002, its urban surface grew to nearly six times its previous size, and the number of inhabitants rose by over 500% [69]. The inhabitants of Santiago are exposed to a high level of atmospheric pollution during autumn and winter as a result of particulate matter which is present at that time, and during spring and summer due to ozone [40]. This has been historically translated into episodes of environmental alert, pre-emergency and emergency states, which have been associated with adverse effects on citizens’ health [41].
As for mining, we have already established that the mining sector plays a remarkable role in the country’s economy and it is consequently well known by the population. This could suggest that people are more aware of the risks and environmental effects and, therefore, perceive it as one of the riskiest sectors with higher environmental impacts than agriculture or fishing. Also, mining impacts are created from a few significant projects, rather than agriculture or fishing, which are distributed along the national territory.

5.3. Acceptability and Its Relation with Perceived Risk and Trust

Our results concur with the literature that empirically demonstrates that acceptability is associated with perceived risk and trust in regulatory institutions [4,5,6,7,11,12]. Moreover, there is evidence which shows that, for environmental hazards, both trust in regulatory institutions and perceived risk would determine social acceptability [13,14,70].
The low trust in regulatory institutions leads people to perceive an activity or technology and its impacts as unacceptable in instances where, under different circumstances, they would have found them to be perfectly acceptable [5]. Therefore, if people do not trust the entities in charge of regulating the environmental hazards, they will also show a lower acceptability of these risks.
Controlling for perceived risk and trust, the economic activity influences the acceptability of an environmental hazard. However, the environment affected—whether it is water, air or soils—do not affect people’s levels of acceptability. In general, people have a low acceptability of the risk imposed to society for the environmental impacts for all sectors. Mining had a significantly lower acceptability than all other activities. Some authors suggest that the public’s unacceptability of risks generated by mining are more related to a lack of education or to the “not in my backyard” idea, and they suggest that no person with a certain level of culture and common sense could oppose the need for mining [71]. However, we advance a different explanation. First, there is a feeling of inequality between the local community that is being affected by mining and those who received its benefits [45]. Viveros (2014) finds that interviewees perceive insufficient royalty rates in comparison to mining companies’ revenues and that economic benefits have not been shared with the affected communities. Second, mining processes are characterized by generating environmental impacts that are generally irreversible. Mining relies on mineral resources that determine where can be located, letting little flexibility to avoid environmental impacts [47]. This would lead the population to oppose such risks. Finally, in the year in which the study was conducted, the Pascua-Lama project was being developed and became a symbol for social opposition to the environmental risks generated and stirred a controversy that even made it to the international level, causing a detrimental effect to the government’s image [46].
Considering the current stage of the mining sector and its future development, regulatory agencies must react quickly to implement policies to improve social trust in decision makers’ actions to regulate environmental mining impacts.

5.4. Compensation Demanded and Its Relation with Perceived Risk, Acceptability and Trust in Authorities

Our results show that compensation demanded depends on how risky the environmental impact is perceived to be, on its acceptability as well on how trusty authorities in charge of regulating those impacts are. Our results agree with the hypothesis that the classical variables used in the field of risk perception are related to each other [11,12,13,14] and are also related to the compensation demanded. Our results support empirically and theoretically that compensation demanded is suitable to be used in this type of relationship when it comes to environmental impacts. People that perceives higher risk for environmental impacts also declared higher compensations, independently of the environment affected. The effect of acceptability on the compensation demanded is negative and depends on the economic activity, thus indicating that there is not only a main effect of acceptability, but also that this increases or decreases depending on the economic activity. Social trust instead has a negative effect over compensation demanded. This might suggest that people whose trust in authorities is low tend to declare higher compensation for the risk posed by environmental impacts in general, but, as we saw from the model, there is no discrimination whether the regulation is for the environment affected or the economic activity behind those impacts. It is interesting to note that in summary, respondents do not seem to discriminate between which environment (air, water, soil, or ocean) is affected when it comes to a demand for compensation. What matters is the economic activity responsible for the impacts and for compensating society for their effect.
Respondents point to mining, the economic activity that generates greater wealth for the country, as the economic activity with the highest compensation demanded. We believe that this is not arbitrary and could be explained by two aspects: First, the “deep pocket” theory, or agents with great wealth [72,73]. This theory postulates that people are inclined to demand greater compensation from those whom they believe are wealthier and more able to afford such compensations [74]. Second, the “defendant identity effect”, where damage compensations are biased according to the identity of the sued party [75].
In Chile, the mining industry, particularly copper, is structured in large-scale mining, represented by 17 private companies and one state-owned enterprise, the National Copper Corporation (Codelco), which is the biggest copper mining company in the world; mid-scale mining, represented by 22 mostly local companies; and minor-scale mining. Only three mining companies, namely Codelco, Escondida and Anglo American are responsible for over 60% of the national production (identity effect). This represented, in 2012, 12.8% of the national GDP and over 62% of total export income [39] (deep pocket theory).
The mining sector in Chile has been a constant theme of public discourse. Mining reflects a source of wealth that has motivated very intense social movements throughout the twentieth century, with clearly visible historic landmarks (e.g., the nationalization of the copper industry). We should realize that the status of the mining industry in Chile occupies a very different place in comparison to that of other activities in the collective imagination.
Since mining is the economic activity with less acceptability, perceived as one of the most risky, and, considering its strong identity in the public imagination (identity effect), as a source of great wealth (deep pocket), it is not unusual that participants demanded greater compensations from this economic activity over the others.
As the main conclusion, we can state that, of all economic activities, the mining environmental impacts are perceived to be least acceptable, with a greater risk and with a greater demanded compensation. Considering Chilean mining’s export profile, government institutions should develop public policies for the mining sector that guarantee the use of natural resources in a sustainable manner and that promote an equitable distribution of the economic benefits and impacts of the activity.
Our results help understand why environmental impacts from certain economic activities are perceived more riskier and less acceptable that those from others, and why society demands higher compensations from them. It is vital then for regulatory institutions to consider this heterogeneity in the way environmental impacts are regulated.

Acknowledgments

This research was partially funded through a research grant from Universidad Diego Portales through the Project Semilla 10.03.25.003 “Confianza y Aceptabilidad Social de Riesgos Ambientales en Chile”. Virna Vaneza Gutiérrez also thanks the support of Conicyt’s Doctoral Scholarship.

Author Contributions

All authors have directly participated in the original idea, planning, execution, or analysis of this study. Virna Vaneza Gutiérrez had the original idea. Both Virna Vaneza Gutiérrez and Nicolás C. Bronfman designed the survey, as well as planned and executed the study. Virna Vaneza Gutiérrez and Luis Abdón Cifuentes performed the statistical analysis and drafted the manuscript. All authors of this paper have read and approved the final submitted version.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Slovic, P. Perception of Risk. Science 1987, 236, 280–285. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Renn, O.; Burns, W.J.; Kasperson, J.X.; Kasperson, R.E.; Slovic, P. The Social Amplification of Risk: Theoretical Foundations and Empirical Applications. J. Soc. Issues 1992, 48, 137–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Flynn, J.; Slovic, P.; Mertz, C.K. Decidedly Different: Expert and Public Views of Risks from a Radioactive Waste Repository. Risk Anal. 1993, 13, 643–648. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Ozawa, S.; Stack, M.L. Public trust and vaccine acceptance-international perspectives. Hum. Vaccin. Immunother. 2013, 9, 1774–1778. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  5. Bronfman, N.; Vázquez, E.; Dorantes, G. An empirical study for the direct and indirect links between trust in regulatory institutions and acceptability of hazards. Saf. Sci. 2009, 47, 686–692. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Gutteling, J.; Hanssen, L.; van der Veer, N.; Seydel, E. Trust in governance and the acceptance of genetically modified food in the Netherlands. Public Underst. Sci. 2006, 15, 103–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Flynn, J.; Burns, W.; Mertz, C.K.; Slovic, P. Trust as a Determinant of Opposition to a High-Level Radioactive Waste Repository: Analysis of a Structural Model. Risk Anal. 1992, 12, 417–429. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Siegrist, M.; Gutscher, H.; Earle, T.C. Perception of risk: The influence of general trust, and general confidence. J. Risk Res. 2005, 8, 145–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Viklund, M. Trust and Risk Perception in Western Europe: A Cross-National Study. Risk Anal. 2003, 23, 727–738. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  10. Siegrist, M.; Cvetkovich, G.T. Perception of Hazards: The Role of Social Trust and Knowledge. Risk Anal. 2000, 20, 713–719. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  11. Bratanova, B.; Morrison, G.; Fife-Schaw, C.; Chenoweth, J.; Mangold, M. Restoring drinking water acceptance following a waterborne disease outbreak: The role of trust, risk perception, and communication. J. Appl. Soc. Psychol. 2013, 43, 1761–1770. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Lee, J.H.; Song, C.H. Effects of trust and perceived risk on user acceptance of a new technology service. Soc. Behav. Pers. 2013, 41, 587–597. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Siegrist, M.A. A Causal Model Explaining the Perception and Acceptance of Gene Technology1. J. Appl. Soc. Psychol. 1999, 29, 2093–2106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Poortinga, W.; Pidgeon, N.F. Trust in Risk Regulation: Cause or Consequence of the Acceptability of GM Food? Risk Anal. 2005, 25, 199–209. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  15. Eiser, J.R.; Miles, S.; Frewer, L.J. Trust, perceived risk, and attitudes toward food technologies. J. Appl. Soc. Psychol. 2002, 32, 2423–2433. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Bronfman, N.C.; Jiménez, R.B.; Arévalo, P.C.; Cifuentes, L.A. Understanding social acceptance of electricity generation sources. Energ. Pol. 2012, 46, 246–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Tanaka, Y. Major Psychological Factors Determining Public Acceptance of the Siting of Nuclear Facilities. J. Appl. Soc. Psychol. 2004, 34, 1147–1165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Sjöberg, L. Local Acceptance of a High-Level Nuclear Waste Repository. Risk Anal. 2004, 24, 737–749. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  19. Huang, L.; Ban, J.; Sun, K.; Han, Y.; Yuan, Z.; Bi, J. The influence of public perception on risk acceptance of the chemical industry and the assistance for risk communication. Saf. Sci. 2013, 51, 232–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Tortosa-Edo, V.; López-Navarro, M.A.; Llorens-Monzonís, J.; Rodríguez-Artola, R.M. The antecedent role of personal environmental values in the relationships among trust in companies, information processing and risk perception. J. Risk Res. 2013, 17, 1019–1035. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Satterfield, T.; Conti, J.; Harthorn, B.H.; Pidgeon, N.; Pitts, A. Understanding shifting perceptions of nanotechnologies and their implications for policy dialogues about emerging technologies. Sci. Public Policy 2013, 40, 247–260. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Bronfman, N.C.; López-Vazquez, E.L.; Gutierrez, V.V.; Cifuentes, L.A. Trust, acceptance and knowledge of technological and environmental hazards in Chile. J. Risk Res. 2008, 11, 755–773. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Baumol, W.J.; Oates, W.E.; Bawa, V.S.; Bradford, D.F. The Theory of Environmental Policy; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  24. Burrows, P. The Economic Theory of Pollution Control; MIT Press: Cambridge, UK, 1980. [Google Scholar]
  25. Cornes, R.; Sandler, T. The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods, 2nd ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  26. Hanemann, W.M. Valuing the environment through contingent valuation. J. Econ. Perspect. 1994, 8, 19–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Smith, V.K. Estimating Economic Values for Nature : Methods for Non-Market Valuation; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  28. Smith, V.K. Can We Measure the Economic Value of Environmental Amenities? South. Econ. J. 1990, 56, 865–878. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Cropper, M.L.; Oates, W.E. Environmental Economics—A survey. J. Econ. Lit. 1992, 30, 675–740. [Google Scholar]
  30. Brown, T.C.; Gregory, R. Why the WTA-WTP disparity matters. Ecol. Econ. 1999, 28, 323–335. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Hammond, K.R.; Anderson, B.F.; Sutherland, J.; Marvin, B. Improving Scientists’ Judgments of Risk. Risk Anal. 1984, 4, 69–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Kahneman, D.; Knetsch, J.L.; Thaler, R.H. Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem. J. Polit. Econ. 1990, 98, 1325–1348. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Frey, B.S.; Oberholzer-Gee, F. The cost of price incentives: An empirical analysis of motivation crowding-out. Am. Econ. Rev. 1997, 87, 746–755. [Google Scholar]
  34. Mansfield, C.; van Houtven, G.L.; Huber, J. Compensating for Public Harms: Why Public Goods Are Preferred to Money. Land Econ. 2002, 78, 368–389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Earle, T.C. Trust in Risk Management: A Model-Based Review of Empirical Research. Risk Anal. 2010, 30, 541–574. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  36. International Monetary Fund. World Economic Outlook Database, April 2013. Available online: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2013/01/index.htm (accesed on 2 April 2014).
  37. International Grand Thornton. Global Dynamism Index. 2013. Available online: http://www.grantthornton.global (accesed on 19 November 2014).
  38. Banco Central de Chile. Cuentas Nacionales de Chile 2008–2012 Versión Digital 2013; Banco Central de Chile: Santiago, Chile, 2013; Available online: http://www.bcentral.cl/estadisticas-economicas/publicaciones-digitales/anuario_ccnn/pdf/Anuario2012.pdf (accesed on 2 April 2014). (In Spanish)
  39. Banco Central de Chile. Indicadores de Comercio Exterior 2013. Available online: http://bcentral.cl (accesed on 2 April 2014). (In Spanish)
  40. Centro de Análisis de Políticas Públicas. Informe País, Estado Del Medio Ambiente En Chile, 2008; Universidad de Chile: Santiago, Chile, 2008; Available online: http://www.uchile.cl/documentos/descargar-informe-en-pdf-10-mb_64137_0_3917.pdf (accesed on 19 november 2014). (In Spanish)
  41. Franck, U.; Leitte, A.M.; Suppan, P. Multiple exposures to airborne pollutants and hospital admissions due to diseases of the circulatory system in Santiago de Chile. Sci. Total Environ. 2014, 468–469, 746–756. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  42. Cifuentes, L.A.; Vega, J.; Kopfer, K.; Lave, L.B. Effect of the fine fraction of particulate matter versus the coarse mass and other pollutants on daily mortality in Santiago, Chile. J. Air Waste Manag. Assoc. 2000, 50, 1287–1298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  43. Borregaard, N.; Bradley, T. Análisis de tres sectores exportadores chilenos. 1999, XV, 42–49. (In Spanish) [Google Scholar]
  44. Villagrán, C. Pascua Lama: Amenaza a la Biodiversidad; OCEANA: Santiago, Chile, 2006. (In Spanish) [Google Scholar]
  45. Viveros, H. Examining Stakeholders’ Perceptions of Mining Impacts and Corporate Social Responsibility. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Urkidi, L. A glocal environmental movement against gold mining: Pascua–Lama in Chile. Ecol. Econ. 2010, 70, 219–227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Ali, S.H.; Faircheallaigh, C.O. Extractive Industries, Environmental Performance and Corporate Social Responsibility. Green. Manag. Int. J. Corp. Environ. Strateg. Pract. 2007, 52, 5–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Ministerio de Minería. Plan de Descontaminación Complejo Industrial Las Ventanas (1992). D.S. N 252. 1992. Available online: http://www.leychile.cl/Navegar?idNorma=11529 (accesed on 2 April 2014). (In Spanish)
  49. Plan de Descontaminación para María Elena y Pedro de Valdivia (1999). Available online: http://www.leychile.cl/Navegar?idNorma=135782 (accesed on 2 April 2014). (In Spanish)
  50. Plan de descontaminación de la Fundición Hernán Videla Lira-Paipote (1995). Available online: http://www.leychile.cl/Navegar?idNorma=10563 (accesed on 2 April 2014). (In Spanish)
  51. Ministerio de Obras Públicas. Estudio de Impacto Ambiental del proyecto “Embalse Punilla, VIII Región”; 2004. Available online: http://seia.sea.gob.cl/seia-web/ficha/fichaPrincipal.php?modo=ficha&id_expediente=6295 (accessed on 20 June 2015). (In Spanish)
  52. Agrocomercial AS Limitada. Estudio de Impacto Ambiental del “Proyecto Agroindustrial del Valle de Huasco”; 2005. Available online: http://seia.sea.gob.cl/seia-web/ficha/fichaPrincipal.php?modo=ficha&id_expediente=1075666 (accessed on 20 June 2015). (In Spanish)
  53. Ministerio de Obras Públicas. Estudio de Impacto Ambiental del proyecto “Embalse Puntilla del Viento, Comunas de Los Andes y San Esteban, V Región”; 2006. Available online: http://seia.sea.gob.cl/seia-web/ficha/fichaPrincipal.php?modo=ficha&id_expediente=1922537 (accessed on 20 June 2015). (In Spanish)
  54. Comisión Nacional del Medio Ambiente (CONAMA). Plan de Prevención y Descontaminación Atmosférica para la Región Metropolitana, (PPDA). D.S. N 16. 1998. Available online: http://www.leychile.cl/Navegar?idNorma=121128 (accessed on 2 April 2014). (In Spanish)
  55. Ministerio de Agricultura. Ley Sobre Recuperación del Bosque Nativoy Fomento Forestal. Public Law 20.283. 2007. Available online: http://www.leychile.cl/Navegar?idNorma=274894 (accesed on 2 April 2014). (In Spanish)
  56. Ministerio de la Secretaría General de la Presidencia. Ley Sobre Bases Generales del Medio Ambiente. Public Law 19.300. 1994. Available online: http://www.leychile.cl/Navegar?idNorma=30667 (accessed on 2 April 2014). (In Spanish)
  57. Lostarnau, C.; Oyarzún, J.; Maturana, H.; Soto, G.; Señoret, M.; Soto, M.; Rötting, T.S.; Amezaga, J. M.; Oyarzún, R. Stakeholder participation within the public environmental system in Chile: major gaps between theory and practice. J. Environ. Manage. 2011, 92, 2470–2478. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  58. Kasperson, R.E.; Golding, D.; Tuler, S. Social Distrust as a Factor in Siting Hazardous Facilities and Communicating Risks. J. Soc. Issues 1992, 48, 161–187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Cvetkovich, G.T.; Löfstedt, R. Social Trust and the Management of Risk; Earthscan Publications Ltd.: London, UK, 1999. [Google Scholar]
  60. Ali, S.H. Trust, Risk and the Public: The Case of the Guelph Landfill Site. Can. J. Sociol. 1997, 22, 481–504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Jardine, C.G.; Banfield, L.; Driedger, S.M.; Furgal, C.M. Risk communication and trust in decision-maker action: a case study of the Giant Mine Remediation Plan. Int. J. Circumpolar Health 2013. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  62. Schmider, E.; Ziegler, M.; Danay, E.; Beyer, L.; Bühner, M. Is It Really Robust? Methodol. Eur. J. Res. Methods Behav. Soc. Sci. 2010, 6, 147–151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Garson, D.G. GLM Univariate, ANOVA and ANCOVA; Statistical Associates Publishers: New York, NY, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  64. Moore, D.S. The Basic Practice of Statistics, 3rd ed.; W.H. Freeman: New York, NY, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  65. Box, G.E.P.; Hunter, W.G.; Hunter, J.S. Statistics for Experimenters: An Introduction to Design, Data Analysis and Model Building; Wiley Series in Probability and Statistics: New York, NY, USA, 1978. [Google Scholar]
  66. Mulsow, S.; Grandjean, M. Incompatibility of sulphate compounds and soluble bicarbonate salts in the Rio Cruces waters: An answer to the disappearance of Egeria densa and black-necked swans in a RAMSAR sanctuary. Ethics Sci. Environ. Polit. 2006, 2006, 5–11. [Google Scholar]
  67. OECD; ECLAC. OECD Environmental Performance Reviews: Chile 2005; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  68. Siegrist, M.; Cvetkovich, G.; Roth, C. Salient value similarity, social trust, and risk/benefit perception. Risk Anal. 2000, 20, 353–362. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  69. Galetovic, A.; Jordán, P. Santiago: ¿Dónde estamos?,¿Hacia dónde vamos? In Santiago. Dónde estamos y hacia dónde vamos; Galetovic, A., Ed.; Centro de Estudios Públicos: Santiago, Chile, 2006; pp. 87–146. (In Spanish) [Google Scholar]
  70. Siegrist, M. The influence of trust and perceptions of risks and benefits on the acceptance of gene technology. Risk Anal. 2000, 20, 195–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  71. Oyarzún, J.; Oyarzún, R. Minería Sotenible: Principios y Prácticas; GEMM-Aula: Madrid, Spain, 2011. (In Spanish) [Google Scholar]
  72. Hammitt, J.K.; Carroll, S.J.; Relles, D.A. Tort Standards and Jury Decisions. J. Legal Stud. 1985, 14, 751–762. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Chin, A.; Peterson, M.A. Deep Pockets, Empty Pockets: Who Wins in Cook County Jury Trials; RAND Corporation: Santa Monica, CA, USA, 1985. [Google Scholar]
  74. Hans, V.P.; Ermann, M.D. Responses to corporate versus individual wrongdoing. Law Hum. Behav. 1989, 13, 151–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. MacCoun, R. Differential treatment of corporate defendants by juries: an examination of the “Deep-pockets” Hypothesis. Law Soc. Rev. 1996, 30, 121–161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Gutiérrez, V.V.; Cifuentes, L.A.; Bronfman, N.C. Factors Influencing Compensation Demanded for Environmental Impacts Generated by Different Economic Activities. Sustainability 2015, 7, 9608-9627. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su7079608

AMA Style

Gutiérrez VV, Cifuentes LA, Bronfman NC. Factors Influencing Compensation Demanded for Environmental Impacts Generated by Different Economic Activities. Sustainability. 2015; 7(7):9608-9627. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su7079608

Chicago/Turabian Style

Gutiérrez, Virna Vaneza, Luis Abdón Cifuentes, and Nicolás C. Bronfman. 2015. "Factors Influencing Compensation Demanded for Environmental Impacts Generated by Different Economic Activities" Sustainability 7, no. 7: 9608-9627. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su7079608

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop