Next Article in Journal
Sensory Relevance of Strecker Aldehydes in Wines. Preliminary Studies of Its Removal with Different Type of Resins
Previous Article in Journal
Partitioning of Proteins and Anti-Nutrients in Cassava (Manihot esculenta Crantz) Leaf Processing Fractions after Mechanical Extraction and Ultrafiltration
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Food Import Dependency and National Food Security: A Price Transmission Analysis for the Wheat Sector

Department of Economics, Setsunan University, 17-8 Ikedanakamachi, Neyagawa, Osaka 572-8508, Japan
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Submission received: 9 June 2021 / Revised: 14 July 2021 / Accepted: 14 July 2021 / Published: 23 July 2021
(This article belongs to the Section Grain)

Abstract

:
Agricultural trade liberalization and protecting domestic markets encompass conflicting policy goals. Even though after the food crisis in 2008, national governments of food-deficit nations aimed at reducing food supply dependency on external markets, no research has assessed the impacts of food import reliance on price or price volatility transmissions to local markets. We constructed a dynamic conditional correlation (DCC)–generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (GARCH) model to examine whether wheat import dependency could make a country vulnerable to overseas shocks by analyzing the inter-relationships between the international wheat price and retail wheat flour prices in 10 net importing countries over the sample period from January 2005 to December 2019. It was found that retail price volatility in each region was positively correlated with international price volatility for most of the period concerned. We also discovered that external dependency could significantly protect the domestic market from the global one, implying that lowering wheat dependency on foreign markets improves “stability” and “availability” of food security without sacrificing “utilization”, but it may aggravate “access”.

1. Introduction

Today, food insecurity in a region is often caused in remote areas through international trade. Over the last decades, this trend has been consolidated by multilateral or bilateral free trade agreements. Additionally, unconventional factors to jolt food markets such as hedge funds’ speculative money and biofuel production amplify international market volatility transmitted to vulnerable local markets in food-deficit countries. First-generation biofuel production limits arable land space, which could affect food markets. Furthermore, climate change induces extreme weather and destabilizes agricultural productivity and therefore market prices [1]. For example, a poor wheat harvest occurred due to extreme drought in Australia and Ukraine in 2007, which increased the global wheat price with a low level of global inventory, export restrictions, and financial speculative activities [2]. Thus, today, securing food supply from domestic or foreign markets is more difficult under such conditions.
Agricultural trade liberalization and protecting local markets have polarized policy goals. Since the 1980s, nations have signed several multilateral or bilateral free trade agreements to improve the efficiency of resource allocation, and countless citizens have received economic benefits from trade. In the wake of the 2008 global food crisis that worsened global food insecurity, extending the hunger population by 44 million [3], many national governmental bodies, such as those of Senegal, India, the Philippines, Qatar, and Bolivia, expressed interest in food self-sufficiency policy [4]. In other words, various countries are attempting to establish robust food supply systems to prepare for the uncertainty that could happen in agricultural international markets. Food autarky is broadly regarded as an effective strategy for national food security by policymakers. This policy measure could reduce the degree of international price transmissions, which may interest the aforementioned governments.
The existing literature regarding price transmission of food commodities is abundant, with over 500 recently published papers resulting from an AgEcon database search with the term “price transmission” [5]. Many papers analyze price pass-throughs within developing countries (e.g., [6,7,8,9,10,11,12,13]). Fewer papers explore price correlations from global to local markets (e.g., [14,15,16,17,18]), many of which apply error correction models to establish the international market connections. The only paper that investigates international price volatility transmissions in agricultural sectors was by Ceballos et al., in which a bivariate threshold Baba, Engle, Kraft and Kroner (BEKK)- generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (GARCH) model is used [19]. However, most of the price transmission analyses mentioned above fail to explore the potential determinants behind international price pass-throughs. Guo and Tanaka examined the effectiveness of self-sufficiency in wheat for wheat importers and exporters, respectively [8,20]. They discovered that a high autarky rate has the potential to weaken price volatility transmissions between global and local markets.
This paper focuses on the identification of potential factors behind international price volatility transmissions of wheat, using GARCH- dynamic conditional correlation (DCC) models over the period from January 2005 to December 2019. We first estimated the time-variant relationship between world and regional prices, and then we regressed the estimated DCC or asymmetric dynamic conditional correlation (ADCC) by potential transmission factors such as wheat import dependency, gross domestic product (GDP), consumer price index (CPI), exchange rates, and the consumption of substitutive goods such as rice, corn, and barley.
The contribution of this research to the literature is to discover the potential determinants of international price volatility pass-throughs concentrating on net wheat import or dependency on foreign suppliers. Even though there exists a large body of literature on agricultural price transmissions as stated above, only a few articles attempt to find the potential drivers behind price or price volatility transmissions [8,20,21]. The past research concentrates on self-sufficiency policy in agricultural commodities, but no article discusses the role of food import dependency in the connectedness between global and local markets. The outcomes from our experiments are useful for policymakers to prevent unexpected price fluctuations of local food markets in terms of national food security.
This paper is organized as follows. The “Methodology” section describes the empirical models and data used in the present paper. The next section presents the results, interpretations of the outputs, and policy implications. Finally, the “Conclusion” section summarizes the article and mentions future research directions.

2. Materials and Methods

We used a two-step econometric methodology to analyze the price volatility transmission between global and local wheat prices. First, we employed a dynamic conditional correlation–generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (DCC-GARCH) model to estimate the volatility spillovers between global and local wheat prices. Second, a panel analysis was applied to investigate the common factors affecting the volatility spillovers between global and local wheat prices.

2.1. Estimating Volatility Transmission Using DCC-GARCH Models

Since Bollerslev introduced the generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (GARCH) process to forecast univariate financial asset volatilities, the theory of multivariate GARCH (MGARCH) models has developed to reveal the co-volatilities of multiple asset prices [22]. Among these, the DCC-GARCH model developed by Engle represents a computational advancement when estimating large covariance matrices to describe the time-varying correlation between asset prices [23]. This paper, therefore, employs a DCC-GARCH model to analyze the volatility transmission between global and local wheat prices.
In a DCC-GARCH model, the mean equation is
p t = c + i = 0 k a i p t i + u t
where pt is a 2 × 1 vector including the logarithmic returns of global and local wheat prices, p1,t and p2,t, respectively; c is a 2 × 1 constant vector where c = (c1,c2)′; ai is the coefficient which captures the autoregressive effect. The lag length k could be determined by an information criterion; ut is a 2 × 1 forecast errors vector where ut = (u1,t,u2,t)′.
The variance equation follows a DCC-GARCH process as
u t = H t ε t H t = D t R t D t D t = d i a g h 11 , t , h 22 , t R t = d i a g Q t 1 2 Q t d i a g Q t 1 2 Q t = 1 λ 1 λ 2 Q ¯ + λ 1 u ˜ i , t 1 u ˜ j , t 1 + λ 2 Q t 1
where Ht is a 2 × 2 conditional variance–covariance matrix; εt is a 2 × 1 vector of normal, independent, and identically distributed innovations; Rt is a 2 × 2 symmetric dynamic correlations matrix; Dt is a 2 × 2 diagonal matrix of conditional standard deviations for forecast residuals; Qt is a 2 × 2 time-varying covariance matrix of standardized residuals ũi,t = ui,i/hi,t; and Q ¯ is the unconditional correlation as ũi,t−1ũj,t−1. Constraints that both λ1 and λ2 are non-zero and λ1 + λ2 < 1 to keep the volatility convergence are set. If λ1 + λ2 = 1, it becomes a constant conditional correlation GARCH model (CCC-GARCH), which has no conditional variance and covariance between prices. The computational advancement of the DCC-GARCH model is that conditional variances h11,t and h22,t in Ht are estimated by a univariate GARCH process as
h i , t = b i , 0 + b i , 1 u i , t 1 2 + b i , 2 h i , t 1
where bi,0, bi,1, and bi,2 are coefficients.
Furthermore, ref. [24] introduced the asymmetric DCC-GARCH (ADCC-GARCH) model, which modifies the correlation evolution equations with an asymmetry as
Q t = 1 λ 1 λ 2 Q ¯ δ N ¯ + λ 1 u ˜ i , t 1 u ˜ j , t 1 + λ 2 Q t 1 + δ ( η t 1 η t 1 )
where N ¯ represents the unconditional matrices of η t = I [ u ˜ i , t < 0 ] u ˜ i , t where is the Hadamard product; I[.] is an indicator function equal to 1 if ũi,t < 0 and 0 otherwise; λ1 and λ2 have the same definition and constraints as in the DCC-GARCH model.
The parameters in DCC-GARCH and ADCC-GARCH models are estimated using the quasi-maximum likelihood method (QMLE). Under the Gaussian assumption, the log-likelihood function is
LL = 1 2 1 2 2 log 2 π + log D t 2 + u t D t 1 D t 1 u t + log R t + u ˜ t R t 1 u ˜ t u ˜ t u ˜ t

2.2. Estimating Common Factors for DCC Using Panel Analysis

In the next step, we analyzed which common factors affect the volatility transmission between global and local prices by using a panel analysis as
D C C i , t = μ 0 + μ 1 D e p e n d e n c e i , t + μ 2 G D P i , t + μ 3 C P I i , t + μ 4 Δ e r i , t + j = 1 3 γ j Δ S C j , t + d y e a r + d c o u n t r y + ε i , t
where DCC is the annualized dynamic conditional correlations between global and local wheat prices calculated by DCC-GARCH models; Dependence is the degree of dependence on wheat import calculated by D e p e n d e n c e i , t = N e t   I m p o r t i , t w h e a t   c o n s u m p t i o n i , t × 100 ; GDP is the annual GDP per capita growth rate; CPI is the annual inflation rate; ∆er is the logarithm exchange rate returns of the local currency against the US dollar; ∆SC is the logarithmic change rates of consumption in substitute goods, including barley, maize, and rice; dyear and dcountry are year and country dummies; εi,t is the heteroskedastic error term; μ and γ are coefficients to be estimated.
Table 1 shows the expected signs of coefficients estimated in Equation (6).
We assume the following: (1) A higher degree of dependence on wheat imports and the local currency depreciation against the US dollar will weaken the volatility transmission between global and local wheat prices, resulting in a higher DCC. (2) Inflation in local prices and increases in consumption of substitute goods will strengthen volatility transmission between global and local wheat prices. More importantly, as wheat is a necessary good, the price elasticity to incomes is assumed positive.

2.3. Data

This analysis concentrates on assessing the impacts of import dependency in wheat on price volatility transmissions between global and local markets. Accordingly, we chose only net importers of wheat with long time series data to extend the sample size. Since wheat is not directly consumed by households, wheat flour prices were collected for domestic prices. We gathered data from the Global Information and Early Warning System (GIEWS), which offers monthly agricultural commodity prices by country. Retail flour prices from January 2005 to December 2019 for 10 wheat-importing countries (Armenia, Brazil, Cameroon, Georgia, Kyrgyzstan, Peru, South Africa, Japan Mexico, and South Korea) were obtained. Commodity price data for many nations in the GIEWS are available, but we found only 10 regions that meet our requirements, such as the availability of data on retail prices of wheat flour for a recent period and being non-self-sufficient in wheat. Following the literature (e.g., [20]), both the global wheat price and local wheat prices were invoiced in the US dollar. The global wheat price is the export price of wheat (the US No. 2 hard red winter) from the US Gulf Coast, which is also quoted in the GIEWS. Table 2 shows the variables employed in panel analysis.

3. Results

3.1. Dynamic Conditional Correlations between Global and Local Wheat Prices

Figure 1 shows the movement in the logarithmic returns of global and local wheat prices. Both global and local wheat prices volatilize mainly within a range of ±20% during the entire sample period and experienced large price volatility after the 2008 Global Financial Crisis.
Table 3 reports the descriptive statistics and the augmented Dicky–Fuller (ADF) test statistics of wheat price returns. Both the global price and local prices in most importer countries averagely increased from January 2008 to December 2018, except South Korea and Peru. The augmented Dicky–Fuller (ADF) test on global and all local price returns rejects the null hypothesis that there is a unit root at a 1% significant level, showing stationarity at the level.
In addition, we applied the Granger causality test between global and local price returns by country to find the causality with one- or two-period (month) lag. The results in Table 4 shows that, for most wheat importer countries, there is significant Granger causality from the global price return to local price returns, expressing the large dominant power of the global price on local prices. For Armenia, Brazil, and South Korea, there are significant Granger causalities from local price returns to global returns, showing the local prices of importer countries could even affect the global price. Conversely, for Japan and South Africa, there are no significant Granger causalities.
Regarding the stationarity and Granger causality of sample data, we estimated four types of DCC-GARCH models, as mentioned in the methodology: the DCC-GARCH model, the DCC-GARCH model with autoregressive effect in mean equation (AR-DCC-GARCH), the ADCC-GARCH model, and the ADCC-GARCH model with autoregressive effect in the mean equation (AR-ADCC-GARCH). Table 5 reports the DCC-GARCH model selection by Bayesian information criterion (BIC). It is notable that, for some model settings, dynamic conditional correlation could not be estimated by the maximum likelihood method, possibly due to the small sample size. After excluding the inestimable model settings (represented by a hyphen in Table 5), the best model selections for countries were chosen by BIC: DCC-GARCH models for Cameroon, Japan, and Kyrgyzstan; an AR-DCC-GARCH model for South Korea; ADCC-GARCH models for Brazil, Georgia, and South Africa; AR-ADCC-GARCH models for Armenia, Mexico, and Peru.
Table 6 presents the estimation results of the parameter metrics for the DCC models with specifications selected by BIC, which are shown in Table 5. First, every model specification fits the condition of λ1 + λ2 ≤ 1, indicating that the dynamic conditional correlation for all pairs of global and domestic wheat prices is mean reverting (convergent). Second, the coefficient λ2 is observed to be positive and significant for most model specifications, showing the autoregressive effect that the lagged dynamic conditional correlation significantly affects the current dynamic conditional correlations. Third, the asymmetric coefficients, δ, are found to be positive, indicating the asymmetric response in the correlation between global and domestic wheat prices, although it is not statistically significant at a 10% significant level for all selected model specifications possibly due to the limitation on data size.
Figure 2 represents the estimated dynamic conditional correlations between global and domestic prices, following the model specifications selected by BIC.
Overall, the movements in dynamic conditional correlations show strong time variability in the sample period and considerable country dependence. For almost the entire sample period, dynamic conditional correlations are positive for sample countries, showing that the high volatility of the global wheat price could lead to an increase in the volatility of local wheat prices. Further, we also found that the dynamic conditional correlations could become negative in a very short time after shocks. For example, the DCC for Japan became negative after the 2008 Global Financial Crisis, showing the different movements between global and local prices. The same scenario also happened in Kyrgyzstan and South Korea after the shock in 2017. Therefore, shocks could affect the conditional correlation between global and local prices, showing the different responses of global and local wheat markets. Finally, we found a significant time trend of the dynamic conditional correlation in some sample countries such as Armenia, Cameroon, and Japan. For example, the DCC in Cameroon experienced a sharp decrease after the 2008 Global Financial Crisis and then stabilized around 0.3 from 2012 to 2018.
Further, Table 7 indicates the descriptive statistics of monthly DCC between global and local wheat prices. We found that, during the sample period, all country DCCs have positive means, displaying the increasing volatility spillovers between global and local wheat prices in import countries. The ranges of DCCs largely varied depending on the country. For example, the Armenian DCC range was 0.068, while the Mexican DCC range was 0.759, showing the different movements of DCC.
Figure 2 signifies the DCC pairs between the global wheat price and retail wheat flour prices. It is observed that the DCCs for all regions over the sample period never take negative values, except those for Japan in the food crisis (2007–2008) period and Kyrgyzstan and South Korea around 2017. This suggests that greater price volatility in the global market tends to cause larger price volatility in local markets. It is interesting that the dynamic correlations dramatically fluctuate around the 2008 food price surges in most of the nations (Armenia, Brazil, Cameroon, Mexico, South Korea, Peru, and South Africa), while the connectedness largely varies over time and across regions. The mean of the correlations is positive in all regions. Cameroon has the highest average estimate of the DCC (0.306), while Armenia shows the lowest value (0.072).

3.2. Panel Data Analysis

Table 8 exhibits the results of the panel data analysis. It is indicated that the coefficients of dependency on foreign markets are positive and significant for all models following the hypothesis. The experimental outcomes confirm that the net import of wheat is a potential determinant for international price transmission and that larger foreign supply reliance induces greater spillovers to local markets. We also found that CPI is positive and significant for DCC in all models. This implies that international market connectivity is strengthened by high inflation. This is because, when the relative domestic wheat or wheat flour price to the counterpart in overseas markets becomes high, consumers prefer foreign products, leading to an increase in wheat imports. As such, the importing retail prices are more sensitively influenced by the global price. Moreover, the outcomes tell us that substitutive goods such as barley, maize, and rice do not significantly function as a shock absorber for domestic wheat flour markets, which differ from the hypothesis.

3.3. Policy Implications

Our results indicate that reducing the foreign dependency on wheat could significantly abate the conveyance of international market shocks to indigenous markets. This partially bolsters the efficacy of the food self-sufficiency policy that gained the attention of food-deficit nations especially after the 2008 food price spikes. For instance, since the Second World War, the food self-sufficiency of Japan on a calorie basis has almost halved to approximately 40%, and the central government has long attempted to push up its food autarky rate by protecting domestic markets from global markets. Because the wheat self-sufficiency in Japan is achieved with around 10% imported from major exporters such as the US, Australia, and Canada, reducing reliance on foreign suppliers could stabilize local prices. After the global commodity boom in 2008, many developing countries suffered the price spikes of bread, a primary diet commodity, and people sparked off food riots [25]. Egypt, the largest importer of wheat, experienced food riots in 2011 and 2017 [26,27], which may have been prevented with the policy measure.
Due to the discovery of cows with bovine spongiform enteropathy in the United States around 2004, Japan’s government restricted beef imports from the country, which caused substitutive behavior with many restaurants replacing beef meals with pork ones immediately after the event. In this context, our analysis uncovered that substitutive grain consumption behavior was not useful for alleviating shocks from external markets. However, the result explains only the short-term impact, and long-term effects may be different. Namely, cereal substitution could occur in the long run, mitigating price volatility transmission from world markets. However, the diversification of food consumption patterns must be beneficial in terms of financial risk management for households. Consumers who have eating habits of just wheat-based products are economically susceptible to wheat price fluctuations, compared with those who consume a variety of grain-based food products. Japan is a good example of diversifying food goods. Before the end of the Second World War, the citizens of Japan depended only on traditional Japanese meals. This was largely changed with the introduction of Western-style foods to school lunches by the General Headquarters of the Supreme Commander of Allied Powers that reigned over the nation. Consequently, the population in the country consumes a wide range of international meals today. Although it would take a long time to actualize food consumption diversity, the policy implementation cost to maintain the eating habits of nationals does not seem to be large once it is realized.
Food security comprises four aspects: “availability”, “access”, “stability”, and “utilization”. From these viewpoints, our results suggest that, assuming that domestic wheat production is boosted by, for instance, a higher import tariff or additional farming subsidy, the reduction of food supply dependency improves “availability”. The resulting lower external supply dependency could improve “stability”. From the perspective of farmers, the reduction of price volatility under the autarky system improves their price forecast, which increases farmers’ expected utility levels.

4. Conclusions

This paper examines the potential determinants of international price volatility pass-throughs for the wheat sector, applying DCC-GARCH and panel data models. Our primary results are as follows: (1) the global wheat price and the retail price of wheat flour are positively correlated over time; (2) lowering reliance on foreign suppliers weakens the connectedness between global and local prices; (3) substitutive grain commodities such as barley, maize, and rice do not absorb jolts from overseas markets.
This research focused on the identification of cross-boundary price volatility transmission and its underlying factors. In policy decision-making processes, the implementation cost needs to be estimated to compare the benefits from the policy. As stated, the central government of Japan could not enhance food autarky rates even when allocating a considerable amount of subsidy. Even if self-sufficiency were hoisted, the policy should not be carried out if the comprehensive beneficial effects are smaller than the financial burden. Therefore, the favorable impacts from stabilizing domestic markets also need to be assessed. These subjects are beyond the scope of this paper and left for future research.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, T.T.; methodology, P.L.; data curation, T.T.; coding, P.L.; formal analysis, P.L. and T.T.; writing—original draft preparation, P.L. and T.T.; visualization, P.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The dataset used in this research is available in the Global Information and Early Warning System: https://fpma.apps.fao.org/giews/food-prices/tool/public/#/home and Food and Agriculture Organization STAT: http://www.fao.org/faostat/en/#data.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors of this paper declare that they have no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Erhan, G.; Karapinar, B.; Tanaka, T. Welfare-at-Risk and Extreme Dependency of Regional Wheat Yields: Implications of a Stochastic CGE Model. J. Agric. Econ. 2018, 69, 18–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Tanaka, T.; Hosoe, N.; Qiu, H. Risk Assessment of Food Supply: A Computable General Equilibrium Approach; Cambridge Scholars Publishing: Cambridge, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  3. World Bank. Food Price Hike Drives 44 Million People into Poverty. No: 2011/333/PREM, 2011. Available online: https://reliefweb.int/report/bangladesh/food-price-hike-drives-44-million-people-poverty (accessed on 20 July 2021).
  4. Clapp, J. Food self-sufficiency: Making sense of it, and when it makes sense. Food Policy 2017, 66, 88–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Kouyaté, C.; von Cramon-Taubadel, S. Distance and border effects on price transmission: A meta-analysis. J. Agric. Econ. 2016, 67, 255–271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Abdulai, A. Spatial price transmission and symmetry in the Ghanaian maize market. J. Dev. Econ. 2000, 63, 327–349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Baulch, B. Transfer costs, spatial arbitrage, and testing for food market integration. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 1997, 79, 477–487. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Guo, J.; Tanaka, T. Determinants of international price volatility transmission: The role of self-sufficiency rates in wheat-importing countries. Palgrave Commun. 2019, 5, 124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Lutz, C.; Kuiper, W.E.; van Tilburg, A. Maize market liberalisation in Benin: A case of hysteresis. J. Afr. Econ. 2007, 16, 102–133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Myers, R.J. Evaluating the effectiveness of inter-regional trade and storage in Malawi’s private sector maize markets. Food Policy 2013, 41, 75–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Rashid, S. Spatial integration of maize markets in post-liberalised Uganda. J. Afr. Econ. 2004, 13, 102–133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Sayed, A.; Auret, C. Volatility transmission in the South African white maize futures market. Eurasian Econ. Rev. 2020, 10, 71–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Conforti, P. Price Transmission in Selected Agricultural Markets; FAO Commodity and Trade Policy Research Working Paper No. 7; Food and Agriculture Organization: Rome, Italy, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  14. Minot, N. Transmission of World Food Price Changes to Markets in Sub-Saharan Africa; IFPRI Disc. Paper 1059; International Food Policy Research Institute: Washington, DC, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  15. Mundlak, Y.; Larson, D. On the transmission of world agricultural prices. World Bank Econ. Rev. 1992, 6, 399–422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Quiroz, J.; Soto, R. International Price Signals in Agricultural Prices: Do Governments Care? Documento de Investigacion 88, ILADES Postgraduate Economics Program; Universidad Alberto Hurtado: Santiago, Chile; Georgetown University: Washington, DC, USA, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  17. Robles, M.; Torero, M. Understanding the impact of high food prices in Latin America. Economia 2010, 10, 117–164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Ceballos, F.; Hernandez, M.A.; Minot, N.; Robles, M. Grain price and volatility transmission from international to domestic markets in developing countries. World Dev. 2017, 94, 305–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Tanaka, T.; Guo, J. How does the self-sufficiency rate affect international price volatility transmissions in the wheat sector? Evidence from wheat-exporting countries. Humanit. Soc. Sci. Commun. 2020, 7, 26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Guo, J.; Tanaka, T. The Effectiveness of Self-Sufficiency Policy: International Price Transmissions in Beef Markets. Sustainability 2020, 12, 6073. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Bollerslev, T. Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. J. Econom. 1986, 31, 307–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Engle, R. Dynamic conditional correlation: A simple class of multivariate generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models. J. Bus. Econ. Stat. 2002, 20, 339–350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Cappiello, L.; Engle, R.F.; Sheppard, K. Asymmetric dynamics in the correlations of global equity and bond returns. J. Financ. Econom. 2006, 4, 537–572. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. World Bank. Food Riot Radar. Available online: https://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/poverty/food-price-crisis-observatory#4 (accessed on 20 July 2021).
  25. BBC. Egypt Protests: Three Killed in ’Day of Revolt’ 26 January 2011. Available online: https://www.bbc.com/news/world-africa-12272836 (accessed on 17 May 2021).
  26. Middle East Eye. Egypt Bread Riots: Protests Erupt after Subsidy Cut Hits Poor. 8 March 2017. Available online: https://www.middleeasteye.net/news/egypt-bread-riots-protests-erupt-after-subsidy-cut-hits-poor (accessed on 17 May 2021).
  27. Moser, C.; Barrett, C.; Minten, B. Spatial integration at multiple scales: Rice markets in Madagascar. Agric. Econ. 2009, 40, 281–294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The movements in global and local wheat prices returns. ARM, BRA, CMR, GEO, globe, JPN, KGZ, KOR, MEX, PER, and ZAF stand for Armenia, Brazil, Cameroon, Georgia, global, Japan, Kirgizstan, South Korea, Mexico, Peru, and South Africa, respectively.
Figure 1. The movements in global and local wheat prices returns. ARM, BRA, CMR, GEO, globe, JPN, KGZ, KOR, MEX, PER, and ZAF stand for Armenia, Brazil, Cameroon, Georgia, global, Japan, Kirgizstan, South Korea, Mexico, Peru, and South Africa, respectively.
Foods 10 01715 g001
Figure 2. The movements in volatility transmissions. The panels show the movements in dynamic conditional correlations between global and local wheat prices calculated by the DCC-GARCH model.
Figure 2. The movements in volatility transmissions. The panels show the movements in dynamic conditional correlations between global and local wheat prices calculated by the DCC-GARCH model.
Foods 10 01715 g002
Table 1. Assumptions on panel analysis results.
Table 1. Assumptions on panel analysis results.
Dependent VariablesDependenceMacroeconomic FactorsChanges in Consumption of Substitute Goods
GDPCPIerSCbarleySCmazeSCrice
Expected signs+++
Note: This table shows the expected signs of the coefficients in panel analysis on DCC by Equation (6).
Table 2. Panel analysis variable descriptions.
Table 2. Panel analysis variable descriptions.
VariableDescriptionsSource
DCCAnnualized dynamic conditional correlation between logarithmic returns of international and local wheat prices (unit: percentage)Authors’ calculation
DependenceDegree of dependence of local wheat consumption on import, calculated by n e t   w h e a t   i m p o r t l o c a l   w h e a t   c o n s u m p t i o n × 100 (unit: percentage)FAOSTAT; authors’ calculation
GDPAnnualized growth rate of gross domestic product per capita (unit: percentage)FSI
CPICustomer price index (unit: percentage)FSI
erLogarithmic return of exchange rate of local currency against the US dollar (unit: percentage)FSI; authors’ calculation
SCLogarithmic return of consumption of substitute goods, including barley, maize, and rice (unit: percentage)FAOSTAT; authors’ calculation
Table 3. Descriptive statistics and augmented Dickey–Fuller test statistics of wheat price returns.
Table 3. Descriptive statistics and augmented Dickey–Fuller test statistics of wheat price returns.
VariableMeanMedianMinimumMaximumStandard DeviationSkewnessKurtosisADF
ARM−0.33−0.16−12.717.242.70−0.904.61−6.30 ***
BRA0.05−0.65−21.5914.536.21−0.130.19−7.98 ***
CMR−0.35−0.08−25.5617.914.66−1.308.50−11.40 ***
GEO−0.13−0.18−17.1811.603.94−0.472.69−6.95 ***
Globe−0.36−0.88−23.2024.976.550.302.52−9.52 ***
JPN0.250.32−7.1510.362.910.321.11−6.10 ***
KGZ−0.25−0.37−8.6916.923.951.203.82−5.14 ***
KOR0.010.20−17.0826.224.190.7413.09−8.57 ***
MEX−0.060.10−17.2010.113.21−0.824.91−7.99 ***
PER0.11−0.06−3.904.431.360.351.28−7.26 ***
ZAF−0.07−0.18−18.2913.734.30−0.141.68−7.32 ***
Note: *** p < 0.01.
Table 4. Granger causality test.
Table 4. Granger causality test.
LagArmeniaBrazilCameroonGeorgiaKyrgyzstanPeru
121212121212
global→local22.38 ***13.93 ***4.63 **3.38 **0.871.1823.57 ***14.49 ***25.81 ***12.87 ***9.22 ***5.18 ***
local→global0.122.35 *2.612.67 *2.52.43 *0.240.670.140.720.061.13
LagSouth AfricaJapanMexicoSouth Korea
12121212
global→local0.911.130.080.193.16 *5.96 ***6.04 **3.77 **
local→global1.482.21.150.630.380.334.94 **3.46 **
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 5. The model selection of four specifications for DCC GARCH models.
Table 5. The model selection of four specifications for DCC GARCH models.
GARCH ModelARMBRACMRGEOJPNKGZKORMEXPERZAF
AR–ADCC11.352 *13.40412.33512.51911.904-12.15412.026 *10.041 *-
ADCC11.54313.344 *12.33912.476 *11.87912.23912.08912.04110.04412.525 *
AR–DCC--12.33312.48711.87-12.015 *---
DCC--12.313 *-11.845 *12.204 *11.967---
Note: * denotes the best model selection by BIC criterion, while - denotes no dynamic conditional correlation could be calculated.
Table 6. Results of DCC-GARCH models.
Table 6. Results of DCC-GARCH models.
ARMBRACMRGEOJPNKGZKORMEXPERZAF
ModelAR-ADCCADCCAR-ADCCDCCDCCADCCAR-DCCAR-ADCCAR-DCCADCC
λ1000.00800.0160.0940.070000
(0.058)(0.372)(0.028)(0.703)(0.023)(0.062)(0.092)(0.266)(0.024)(0.098)
λ20.856 ***0.3420.877 ***0.703 **0.911 ***0.2520.442000.422 ***
(0.33)(0.809)(0.052)(0.299)(0.055)(0.271)(0.66)(1.888)(0.268)(0.195)
δ0.020.26 0.13 0.330.180.27
(0.067)(0.585) (0.273) (0.349)(0.263)(0.329)
Log Likelihood−782.55−930.92−859.18−868.45−825.49−851.38−832.78−831.05−688.17−872.00
BIC11.3513.3412.3112.4811.8512.2012.0212.0210.0412.53
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05. The values in parentheses are standard errors.
Table 7. Descriptive statistics on the estimated DCC.
Table 7. Descriptive statistics on the estimated DCC.
VariablesnMeanStandard DeviationMedianMinimumMaximumRangeSkewnessKurtosisStandard Error
ARM1440.0720.0120.0680.060.1280.0681.7943.9870.001
BRA1440.1480.0780.1170.0580.5670.5092.8559.9460.006
CMR1440.3060.0270.3010.240.4090.1691.3843.0670.002
GEO1440.160.0430.1510.080.3140.2340.9030.9190.004
JPN1440.0630.0370.061−0.060.1510.211−0.7381.5130.003
KGZ1440.240.0820.243−0.0420.7090.7511.1728.6230.007
KOR1440.1930.0540.195−0.0490.4020.451−0.294.2470.004
MEX1440.0930.0930.0640.0280.7880.7594.2522.8870.008
PER1440.2440.0560.2290.1320.5710.4393.02311.9680.005
ZAF1440.280.0830.2550.1270.7820.6552.61710.5090.007
Table 8. Results of panel data analysis.
Table 8. Results of panel data analysis.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Fixed EffectFixed EffectRandom EffectRandom Effect
Dependence0.1209 ***0.1213 ***0.1147 ***0.1151 ***
(0.0395)(0.0422)(0.0375)(0.0404)
GDP−0.13370.1119−0.1223−0.0015
(0.3522)(0.3668)(0.2847)(0.2958)
CPI1.1309 ***1.3106 ***0.9090 ***1.0061 ***
(0.4096)(0.4232)(0.3493)(0.3604)
er−2.71503.39068.388013.1220
(14.9728)(15.8401)(10.1997)(10.7663)
SCbarley −0.0419 −0.0296
(0.0390) (0.0360)
SCmaize 0.0063 0.0161
(0.0489) (0.0452)
SCrice 0.1299 * 0.0680
(0.0740) (0.0544)
Constant 6.3294 *5.1448
(3.4526)(3.7101)
Year dummyYesYesYesYes
Observations1009010090
R20.12120.18830.11230.1583
Adjusted R2−0.01160.02370.07500.0864
F Statistic2.9664 **2.4521 **12.0233 **15.4198 **
Note: * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Luo, P.; Tanaka, T. Food Import Dependency and National Food Security: A Price Transmission Analysis for the Wheat Sector. Foods 2021, 10, 1715. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/foods10081715

AMA Style

Luo P, Tanaka T. Food Import Dependency and National Food Security: A Price Transmission Analysis for the Wheat Sector. Foods. 2021; 10(8):1715. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/foods10081715

Chicago/Turabian Style

Luo, Pengfei, and Tetsuji Tanaka. 2021. "Food Import Dependency and National Food Security: A Price Transmission Analysis for the Wheat Sector" Foods 10, no. 8: 1715. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/foods10081715

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop