Next Article in Journal
Prediction of Technological Change under Shared Socioeconomic Pathways and Regional Differences: A Case Study of Irrigation Water Use Efficiency Changes in Chinese Provinces
Next Article in Special Issue
Environmental and Economic Concerns in Residents’ Attitudes in Punta del Este (Uruguay)
Previous Article in Journal
The Effect of Wheat Moisture and Hardness on the Parameters of the Peleg and Normand Model during Relaxation of Single Kernels at Variable Initial Loading
Previous Article in Special Issue
Sustainable Development of Mountain Hotels through the Implementation of International Management Standards: The Romanian Case
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Inefficiency of the Neoclassical Paradigm in the Promotion of Subjective Well-Being and Socioeconomic, and Environmental Sustainability: An Empirical Test for the Spanish Case

by
Matías Membiela-Pollán
*,
María Alló-Pazos
,
Carlos Pateiro-Rodríguez
and
Félix Blázquez-Lozano
Department of Business, University of A Coruna, 15001 A Coruna, Spain
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2019, 11(24), 7102; https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su11247102
Submission received: 12 November 2019 / Revised: 5 December 2019 / Accepted: 11 December 2019 / Published: 11 December 2019

Abstract

:
The recent literature developed in the field of happiness economics highlights the overvaluation of income and material prosperity as determinants of happiness, and calls into question many of the assumptions of traditional economic theory linked to “rationality” and the “non-satiety” of the consumer. This article aimed to study which factors explain individual subjective well-being, paying special attention to the role of income and the incidence of social variables and focusing on the case of Spain. As a novelty, this research introduces variables such as trust or the perception of justice, among others. Based on the analysis of the European Social Survey and through the estimation of an ordered logit, we find that, in line with the theory of happiness economics, the material aspects do not play a relevant role as explanatory of subjective well-being, unlike social aspects, such as sociability and trust in people (social capital). In addition, our results indicate that in the case of Spain, the most materialistic people are associated with a lower level of happiness. Thus, it seems that the excess of concern for material and economic issues in the pursuit of happiness undermines socioeconomic and environmental sustainability by causing the “wealth destruction effect”.

1. Introduction

Until the nineties of the last century, little attention had been paid to the analysis of subjective well-being in the context of happiness economics. However, in the last thirty years, there is a broad economic literature on happiness with many contributions from psychologists and sociologists [1]. Studies conducted in this area frequently criticize the precepts of neoclassical theory that highlight the figure of homo economicus as a rational being, maximizer of his own interest, neutral in terms of values, and practically asocial [2,3,4]. Along these lines, the microeconomic assumption of non-satiety is exemplary in that the individual as a consumer always wants more. This factor is the main determinant of satisfaction, and there are no extra-economic considerations in it [5,6].
Richard Easterlin’s text [7] gave rise to what is known as the Easterlin paradox or the happiness paradox. According to him, there is no link between the increase of per capita income and the evolution of global subjective well-being [8,9,10]. Specifically, the Easterlin paradox evidenced the error of circumscribing happiness to material prosperity, or of equating social well-being to mere economic welfare [11]. The new approach questions a good part of the traditional assumptions of the economy [12].
Despite Easterlin, several studies shed light along the same lines as neoclassical theory [13,14,15], emphasizing that the excessive consideration of income, status, and hedonic consumption in the promotion of subjective well-being were still very present in different fields, such as in the economy, sociology, marketing or advertising [16]. Moreover, it is the contemporary individual, as [17] expressed, who accepts the neoclassical, reductionist, and utilitarian paradigm, as a guide for his behavior.
Our goal is to study the main determinants of happiness, paying special attention to the Easterlin paradox, thus, deepening the understanding of the question about what is the real role of income as a determinant of subjective well-being. To do this, we have analyzed not only economic but also social factors. Specifically, and as novelty, this study focused on the analysis of happiness in Spain for the period 2002–2014 and highlights the importance of social factors when talking about topics such as sustainability. In this regard, we should note that in recent times, it has become very important to study social factors to address the new challenges faced by society in the achievement of a sustainable development. Authors such as [18] highlight, as in the transitioning process towards a bioeconomy, the involvement of stakeholders and the enhancement of social capital, which may become helpful in the process of achieving social sustainability. In addition, [19] found that when analyzing green human resource management, the role of social sustainability has been less explored than other pillars of sustainability, such as economic or environmental. Thus, the analysis of social factors becomes crucial because it may help to improve the level of subjective well-being and promote the achievement of more sustainable development.
This article is structured as follows: Section 2 analyzes happiness focused on material prosperity and Section 3 explains the effects of hedonic consumption excess. Section 4 presents the empirical model and the research hypotheses. In addition, Section 5 shows the results, and finally, Section 6 concludes the article.

2. Happiness Focused on Material Prosperity

The relentless pursuit of happiness based on material prosperity and its ineffectiveness in the promotion of subjective well-being was addressed in the literature through theories of hedonic adaptation and social comparison.
First, Reference [20] employed the theory of adaptation when studying individual and collective happiness, concluding that the improvement in the objective circumstances of life does not produce lasting effects, but only temporary effects [21,22,23]. In this sense, Reference [7], in the article that gave rise to the happiness paradox, pointed out that the increase in output deepens the desire and increases the range of human aspirations, which means the medium-term neutralization of the expected positive impact on well-being. The author was referring to the adaptability of individuals, in which the parallel evolution of income and aspirations makes any satisfied desire create a new dissatisfied one [24,25].
Two notions reveal the adaptive process: The hedonic treadmill and the satisfaction treadmill [26]. The first is related to the process of adaptation of the subject. For example, an individual who purchases a luxury car immediately begins to feel how well-being that is generated with his purchase decreases. The second one depends on the level of aspiration that separates satisfaction and dissatisfaction [26]. When material conditions improve, individuals increase their aspirations to keep the level of satisfaction, which has, as a consequence, that subjective happiness remains constant even if the objective conditions have grown. When the aforementioned individual visualizes a new sports car, his level of aspiration rises, suffering a decrease in the satisfaction with his newly purchased good [21,22].
These explanations are linked to the finding of [27], who argued that comfort goods (a car, a refrigerator) provide immediate stimuli, short pleasant sensations whose satisfaction does not extend over time [24,28]. These goods are subject to a strong decreasing marginal utility, creating a dependency that forces the maintenance of innovative and growing consumption to continue experiencing the same pleasure.
The effects described by both treadmills move in the same direction and act almost to completely compensate the effect that the increase of income plays on subjective well-being [15,22,29]. In this way, the individual becomes involved in the pursuit of material prosperity because the hedonic adaptation generates new desires and, therefore, the need to satisfy them.
The second cause of the continuous search for material well-being, and also responsible for the inefficiency of income and hedonic consumption as determinants of happiness, is social comparison.
The theory of relative position emphasizes that subjective well-being does not vary with income, consumption, status, or other attributes of the individual. Specifically, it depends on his change in relative position with respect to others [8,28,30,31,32,33].
Reference [7] wondered why within a country and at a given time, there is a positive and consistent relationship between income and subjective well-being, while in the comparison between countries, this link is not strong. The author went back to the relative income explanation of [34], whereby the usefulness of an individual depends not only on his income and/or consumption but also on those of his environment, which the subject takes as a reference group [22]. In this way, an increase in a person’s income will raise his happiness, but if the members of his reference group also experience an increase at the same time, his level of happiness will remain constant. The purchase decisions of certain goods fulfill the function of integrating the consumer into his social environment. In this way, conventions, own or acquired, help the consumer to integrate their consumption decisions with their ego and their aspirations of belonging.
To reflect the meaning of this behavior on subjective well-being, many social surveys raise questions that allow relative income to be approximated both horizontally and vertically. Relative horizontal and vertical income is measured with questions regarding the comparison of their socioeconomic status with that of their peers and the change of their socioeconomic status over time, respectively [35].
Duesenberry’s approach has, however, other consequences that result from the emulation of the consumption of the reference group. In times of important economic crisis, such as the one started in 2008, the income of a significant part of the population was reduced. Many people decided to reduce consumption and, although their decision is rational, consumption presents inelasticity regarding the income. This phenomenon is not only due to the individual’s resistance to losing the status of belonging but to a more pragmatic fact. Indeed, when income increases, progress towards reference groups encourages the acquisition of new and superior quality goods, goods that imply higher costs in terms of taxes, supplies, etc. When the individual observes a continuous reduction of his income, the sale of those goods and their replacement by others is considered, to reduce costs. But the process is time-delayed and expensive, and often the subject suffers losses. This fact, in combination with the resistance to disconnect from his reference group, causes inelasticity of consumption to the negative variation of income.
Social comparison, which is often fueled by institutions and the mass media (television, advertising) [31,36], generates competition and/or positional escalation whose objective is the desire to match and/or overcome the other (the desire to cancel the discomfort caused by the individual in comparison with the environment). This paradigm is the one that normally accompanies positional goods [37] that share some characteristics of the so-called demerit goods or private goods whose possession needs an effort that produces negative externalities, and therefore, an impartial judge, oblivious to the consumer, who tempers this desire for consumption [22].

3. Effects of Hedonic Consumption Excess

There are two main effects of the hedonic consumption excess: The crowding out on interpersonal relationships and the “wealth destruction effect”, affecting social and environmental sustainability.
In recent years the attention paid to the theory of social capital has increased [38,39,40]. It studies the (productive) role developed by networks of interpersonal relationships in the functioning of the economy and society. Social networks are important for the individuals that make them up since they provide them with a set of tangible and intangible assets (physical support, loan of money, information, influence, affection, health) and also because they are the substrate of civil society, which is one of the three pillars, together with the state and the market, that conform to the economic system [17,41].
In parallel with the theory of social capital, happiness economics and psychology have focused on the importance that non-instrumental relationality (relational goods) has for well-being [15,25,29,42,43]. Some authors claim that the intrinsic needs of individuals have been underestimated and that they have a much more significant role than expected. Relationality is thus a basic human need, essential for well-being [44], and the relational goods or communicative/affective and non-instrumental dimension of interpersonal relationships (mutual love, friendship, companionship, identity, sense of belonging) [45,46] constitute a very relevant variable when explaining happiness [10,12,22,29,42] (Figure 1).
Psychologists found positive social relationships when they examined the characteristics of relatively happier people [47]. The reductionism of the neoclassical school expels sociability from its study [5]. This is only taken into account from an instrumental perspective or in response to positional externalities that affect the preferences and choices of the main agent.
The first effect caused by excessive worry about income and material prosperity is the crowding out on time dedicated to interpersonal relationships. Because of the hedonic adaptation and the social struggle, people do not perceive the modification of the aspirations according to the effective circumstances. They spend a great amount of time in obtaining monetary objectives, sacrificing other non-material goods [10,25,48] and overvaluing comfort goods, to the detriment of relational goods that are less exposed to adaptation, aspirations, and social comparison [48]. While they underestimate the utility related to the satisfaction of the consumption of intrinsic needs (time spent with family and friends), they overestimate the characteristics related to the satisfaction of the consumption of extrinsic desires (income and status) [25]; this last question is reinforced by the effects of advertising and the media, as we noted previously.
In summary, the displacement of investment in social networks and the decline of social capital, especially that based on strong bonds (bonding social capital), caused by overwork and excessive concern for material well-being, adversely affects socioeconomic sustainability (social capital and functionality of civil society) and subjective well-being (happiness and life satisfaction) [6]. In an unplanned way, there is a loss of social welfare due to overexertion that, while seeking positive marginal utility of material goods, leads to a negative net result; both for the individual and for the whole of civil society that draws on the linkage between networks of different nature [49].
The second consequence that causes the excessive concern for material prosperity and hedonic consumption is the “wealth destruction effect”, together with the inefficient allocation of resources, because it raises the over-accumulation of material goods above the needs of the individual [22,50].
The individual frequently acquires material goods which ex post utility is far from the perceived ex ante utility (decision utility) that has been influenced by incorrect modeling of preferences and/or failed choices [24,51,52]. In other words, and as an example, the hedonic adaptation and social comparison lead him to acquire, probably without necessity, the latest generation mobile phone, with the expectation of raising his subjective well-being. However, the quick adaptation to the new product creates the need to increase his level of aspirations. This process destroys wealth and contributes to an inefficient allocation of scarce resources due to material over-accumulation beyond real needs.
The wealth destruction effect is analogous to the prisoner’s dilemma game, where the solution to the search for the best relative position, while constituting a Nash equilibrium, directs all agents to inefficient results. As [37] pointed out, competition for relative position is a zero-sum game since the relative gain of one individual corresponds exactly to the loss of another. Therefore, the resources invested in this type of competition are, from an added point of view, a waste that results in an inefficient “crazy race” [50]. In this sense, Reference [31] pointed out that the result is the social and environmental degradation and the depletion of resources (Figure 2).
The consumerist cult, very present in contemporary societies, is responsible for an important number of negative externalities, and beyond the pernicious effect on social capital, outlined above, undermines moral responsibility towards the poor and the excluded, and also towards future generations because it promotes the depletion of resources, the accumulation of waste and the degradation of the environment [53,54,55,56,57].
In summary, the neoclassical postulates, very present in economic science, do not promote individual subjective well-being due to the effect caused by hedonic adaptation and continuous social comparison. In addition, they lead to a deterioration of social capital, understood as a set of networks of relationships of the person, which are important providers of instrumental and expressive resources. In this way, social sustainability is damaged, as well as environmental sustainability, due to the excess of hedonic consumption, which without influencing happiness, provokes the “wealth destruction effect”, the depletion of resources and pollution. Moreover, the absence of green practices in production and consumption (environmental sustainability) circularly affects social parameters, such as health and safety, equity, wellness and well-being (social sustainability) [19].
In recent years, in response to the evidence of relevant negative externalities on sustainability, a strong social movement has been generated whose main objective is to raise awareness about the importance of caring for the environment, which will result in the medium and long term positive effects on well-being, for example [58]. This context has led to the publication of several research papers in journals of economics, sociology, natural sciences, medicine, etc., and even the appearance of journals with a specific focus on the field of sustainability.

4. Empirical Model

The dependent variable in this study is the level of happiness of people residing in Spain during the period 2002–2014. It has been measured through a Likert scale, from 0 to 10 (0 being the value which represented those who feel very unhappy and 10 for those who feel very happy). This variable is discrete and unobservable, and their values are ordered. Thus, the most appropriate model for their estimation is an ordered logit (OL) as stated by [1] who pointed out that the empirical analysis of subjective well-being under the assumption of ordinal comparability is usually conducted through the estimation of an ordered probit (OP) or OL model, depending on the assumptions about the distribution of the error term. On the contrary, when subjective well-being is a cardinal measure, the analysis frequently employs the ordinary least squares (OLS) method. Nevertheless, these authors found that the results of the estimation of an OL model were very similar to those obtained through the estimation of an OLS model, concluding that cardinality assumptions or intertemporal ordinality of the responses to satisfaction surveys modify the results very little. Similar conclusions were found in [59,60,61].
Focusing on the field of economics, the OLS model was used in [7,62,63,64,65], and the estimation with first differences was employed by [66,67,68]. Nevertheless, the OP and OL models were the most used [69,70,71,72,73,74], and that is the reason why an OL was estimated.
In addition, as explanatory variables, three groups were considered: Economic, social, and sociodemographic characteristics. The general specification of the estimated model is as follows:
Y = x β + ε ,
where Y is the dependent variable, x is the vector of independent variables, β the vector of regression coefficients to be estimated and, ε is the error term. As it has been highlighted before, this paper aimed to focus on the role of social factors (specifically, we identify the following characteristics: The possibility of having free time to enjoy, trust or fairness on people, the environmental awareness) besides the economic factors (the level of income, the degree of materialism, or the level of conformism) when explaining the subjective well-being of people. That is the reason why we control both factors, but also include sociodemographic factors (the gender, the age, the level of education, the marital status, the number of children, or level of self-perceived health). Thus, the following regression was estimated:
H a p p i n e s s i j = β 1 w o m a n i j + β 2 a g e i j + β 3 b a s i c e   d u c a t i o n i j + β 4 m a r r i a g e i j + β 5 c h i l d r e n i j + β 6 h e a l t h i j + β 7 f r e e   t i m e i j + β 8 l a c k   o f   t r u s t i j + β 9 u n f a i r   p e o p l e i j + β 10 e n v i r o n m e n t a l   a w a r e n e s s i j + β 11 h i g h   i n c o m e i j + β 12 m a t e r i a l i s t i c i j + β 13 c o n f o r m i s t i j + ε i j

Research Hypotheses

The central hypothesis of this study was to test whether the level of happiness of individuals is influenced by social aspects that go beyond the merely economic and material, and also by aspects of an economic nature. Table 1 shows the set of primary hypotheses employed to analyze this main issue. In addition, and as secondary hypotheses, we also test whether sociodemographic indicators also influence the degree of people’s individual subjective well-being.

5. Data

To analyze the determinants of happiness, the European Social Survey (2017) was studied, specifically the waves of data published every two years for Spain (2002–2014), as shown in Table 2 (at the moment of the conduction of the study, data for the year 2016 was not available). This survey provides information about social values for people living in European countries. Specifically, we studied the explanatory factors of subjective well-being based on three groups of variables: Social, economic, and sociodemographic aspects, as it has been mentioned before. It is noteworthy that the influence of these aspects is analyzed for each of the years in which the survey has been conducted to test whether their effects on happiness are maintained over time.
With regard to demographic characteristics, the average age of the respondents was around 45–48 years. Regarding gender, 50% of the sample corresponded to the female sex. Based on the educational level, we identified respondents who affirmed having a basic education; the average ranged from 27% in 2014 to 49% in 2004. On the other hand, about 50–57% of the people surveyed said they were married, and 40–45% lived with children at home. Finally, in this group of characteristics, self-perceived health was included with the average level greater than 3 (it was measured on a scale of 1 to 5, where 1 represents having very poor health and 5 having very good health).
In the social characteristics group, 50–58% of the sample (depending on the year of study) commented they had free time to meet with friends and family every day or many times a week. In addition, around 71–75% of people surveyed showed some degree of distrust, stating that you have to be cautious with people. Moreover, about 66–73% stated that individuals often take advantage of others. On the other hand, and with regard to issues that go beyond the personal sphere, we also highlight that 69% of respondents were concerned about environmental issues in 2004, while this percentage rose to 82% in 2006.
Finally, the economic aspects showed that between 37% and 58% considered it important to have money, and around 35% affirmed that they lived comfortably with their income. We also underline that between 19% and 36% of the sample declared a high level of income.

6. Results

The results obtained are presented in Table 3. It is important to note that the presence of correlation between the variables was analyzed, finding no evidence in this regard. Specifically, the correlation matrix indicated that none of the coefficients obtained exceed the value of 0.70.
Focusing on the results and regarding the primary hypotheses indicated above, we concluded that social factors matter. Thus, we observed that, in line with [10,15], having free time to interact with friends and family has a positive and statistically significant impact on subjective well-being. In addition, those people who showed greater environmental awareness were also associated with a higher level of happiness (other studies [75,76] express that the relationship is ambivalent). Moreover, exploring social factors that contribute negatively to the level of happiness more deeply, it is important to emphasize that the lack of trust in people, as well as the perception of opportunism (unfair people), impact negatively on the level of happiness of Spanish people (similar results have been obtained by [77,78]).
Analyzing the role of economic factors, those who claimed to live comfortably with their income level (conformist) declared themselves happier. On the contrary, more materialistic people showed lower levels of subjective well-being (as [79] pointed out). If we look at the high income indicator, we observe that it did not constitute a significant determinant to the level of individual happiness (in line with several studies in the field of happiness economics, e.g., [32,80]).
Finally, attending to the results obtained for the set of secondary hypotheses, the role of sociodemographic characteristics, we observe that age had a negative and statistically significant coefficient, which indicates that the younger, the lower the level of happiness (as [81]). Respondents who affirmed to be married (marriage) show higher levels of happiness (a common finding in the literature, e.g., [82,83]). It is also observed that individuals with a basic educational level were linked to a greater degree of happiness for the samples of the years 2006, 2012, and 2014. Another important indicator is related to the state of health; specifically, the results showed that having good health positively influence the level of happiness (as expressed by several authors such as [24,28]). In this group, the indicators being a woman and having children had less statistical significance.
In summary, through this study, we have found that the most material aspects were not associated with a higher level of individual subjective well-being; on the contrary, the most materialistic people were those who revealed lower levels of happiness. In this sense, we can observe how social factors have a positive influence when explaining the level of happiness. In addition, the Easterlin paradox is noted. Thus, there is not a significant link between higher levels of income and the level of subjective well-being.

7. Conclusions and Discussion

This article has criticized the traditional assumptions of economic science (neoclassical paradigm), which displaces from the study any extra-economic consideration when considering the determinants of subjective well-being.
The unreality of the neoclassical approach is evident both by the wide diversity of variables that determine happiness and that elude economic theory and by the Easterlin paradox that consists in the absence of a link between the increase in per capita income and evolution of global subjective well-being. It is not an axiom that higher levels of income and consumption report greater happiness. On the other hand, income and the consequent purchase capacity are subject to the law of diminishing marginal returns. Added to this is the fact that two factors operate in the neutralization of the effect of hedonic consumption on subjective well-being: Hedonic adaptation and social comparison. We have exposed two perverse effects to which the described process leads. On the one hand, the overwork associated with the concern about income and hedonic consumption entails a crowding-out effect on interpersonal relationships, with the consequent deterioration of social capital and subjective well-being. On the other hand, the wealth destruction effect entails the over-accumulation of material goods over the real needs of the individual. The latter results in social and environmental degradation and drives the depletion of resources. That is, the so-called sustainable development is under threat, an issue that we will address in future research.
The results of this study (applied to the Spanish case) support the hypothesis that material aspects have little relevance in promoting subjective well-being, although the influence of income on happiness is subject to the law of diminishing marginal returns. On the other hand, social and sociodemographic aspects, such as trust, lack of perception of opportunism, being married, having free time for friends, and health positively and very significantly influence happiness. In this sense, we conclude that the postulates of the main line of neoclassical thinking, embodied in the figure of homo economicus, are not effective in promoting subjective well-being, while the variables classified as extra-economic have a marked impact on happiness in the case of Spain.
Finally, nowadays there is a great concern about promoting and achieving sustainable development. Climate change is a reality, and current trends of consumption and production are depleting resources and biodiversity. In this regard, a change in behavior is necessary to assure sustainability for future generations. It is important to note that several policies have been designed in this respect; nevertheless, their effectiveness in practice has been limited. One of the causes that could explain this failure could be that they are based on the establishment of economic incentives and therefore, do not pay enough attention to the role of social factors, the strength of networks, or the involvement of people. This study emphasizes that economic factors matter, but they are not the only ones. In fact, results show the importance of social capital. Thus, policymakers should design policies where social factors and social norms should be considered because they influence the level of well-being.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.M.-P., C.P.-R., and F.B.-L.; methodology, M.A.-P. and M.M.-P.; software, M.A.-P.; formal analysis M.M.-P., C.P.-R., and M.A.-P.; investigation, M.M.-P. and F.B.-L.; writing—Original draft preparation, M.M.-P., M.A.-P., and C.P.-R.; writing—Review and editing, F.B.-L., M.M.-P., and M.A.-P.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A.; Frijters, P. How important is methodology for the estimates of the determinants of happiness? Econ. J. 2004, 114, 641–659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Granovetter, M. Economic action and social structure: The problem of embededdness. Am. J. Sociol. 1985, 91, 481–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Sen, A. Sobre Ética y Economía; Alianza Universidad, S. A: Madrid, Spain, 1997. [Google Scholar]
  4. Acosta, W.G.N. El Homo Economicus posmoderno. Rev. Mundo Económico Empresarial 2016, 1, 97–110. [Google Scholar]
  5. Bruni, L. The “technology of happiness” and the tradition of economic science. In Handbook of Economics of the Happiness; Bruni, L., Porta, P.L., Eds.; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2007; pp. 24–53. [Google Scholar]
  6. Membiela Pollán, M. La Teoría del Capital Social; Editorial Camiño do Faro, S.L.: Coruña, Spain, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  7. Easterlin, R. Does economic growth improve the human lot? In Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honour of Moses Abramovitz; David, P.A., Reder, M.W., Eds.; Academic Press, Inc.: New York, NY, USA, 1974. [Google Scholar]
  8. Stevenson, B.; Wolfers, J. Economic Growth and Subjetive-Well-Being: Reassesing the Easterling Paradox; The National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2008; Volume 14282, pp. 1–102. [Google Scholar]
  9. Bartolini, S.; Sarracino, F. Happy for how long? How social capital and economic growth relate to happiness over time. Ecol. Econ. 2014, 108, 242–256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Pena-López, J.A.; Sánchez-Santos, J.M.; Membiela-Pollán, M. Individual social capital and subjective wellbeing: The relational goods. J. Happiness Stud. 2017, 8, 881–901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Abramovitz, M. The welfare interpretation of secular trends in national income and product. In the Allocation of Economic Resources: Essays in Honor of Bernard Francis Haley; Haley, B.F., Abramovitz, M., Alchian, A., Arrow, K.J., Eds.; Stanford University Press Stanford: Redwood City, CA, USA, 1959. [Google Scholar]
  12. Iglesias Vázquez, E.; Pena López, A.; Sánchez Santos, J.M. Bienestar subjetivo, renta y bienes relacionales: Los determinantes de la felicidad en España. Revista Internacional de Sociología 2013, 71, 567–592. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Blanchflower, D.G.; Oswald, A.J. Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. J. Public Econ. 2004, 88, 1359–1386. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Layard, R. Happiness: Lessons from a New Science; Penguin: London, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  15. Bruni, L. The happiness of sociality. Economics and Eudaimonia: A necessary encounter. Ration. Soc. 2010, 22, 383–406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Rojas, M. La Felicidad y el Ingreso en España. In Documento de Trabajo; Facultad Latinoamericana de Ciencias Sociales: Ciudad de México, Mexico, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  17. Etzioni, A. La Dimensión Moral: Hacia Una Nueva Economía; Ediciones Palabra, S.A.: Madrid, Spain, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  18. Falcone, P.M.; González García, S.; Imbert, E.; Lijó, L.; Moreira, M.T.; Tani, A.; Morone, P. Transitioning towards the bio-economy: Assessing the social dimension through a stakeholder lens. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2019, 26, 1135–1153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Amrutha, V.N.; Geetha, S.N. A systematic review on green human resource management: Implications for social sustainability. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 119131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Brickman, P.; Campbell, D.T. Hedonic relativism and planning the good society. In Adaptation-Level Theory: A Symposium; Apley, M.H., Ed.; Academic Press: New York, NY, USA, 1971; pp. 287–302. [Google Scholar]
  21. Diener, E. Subjective well-being: The science of happiness and a proposal for a national index. Am. Psychol. 2000, 55, 34–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  22. Bruni, L. El Precio de la Gratuidad; Editorial Ciudad Nueva: Madrid, Spain, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  23. Edwards, J. Harry Helson’s adaptation-level theory, happiness treadmills and behavioral economics. J. Hist. Econ. Thought 2018, 40, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Easterlin, R. Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. Econ. J. 2001, 111, 465–484. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Becchetti, L.; Trovato, G.; Londono, D.A. Income, relational goods and happiness. Appl. Econ. 2011, 43, 273–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Kahneman, D.; Schwartz, N. Well-Being: The Foundations of Hedonic Psychology; Kahneman, D., Schwartz, N., Eds.; Russell Sage: New York, NY, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  27. Scitovsky, T. The Joyless Economy; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 1976. [Google Scholar]
  28. Haller, M.; Hadler, M. How social relations and structures can produce happiness and unhappiness: An international comparative analysis. Soc. Indic. Res. 2006, 75, 169–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Bartolini, S.; Bilancini, E. If not only GDP, what else? Using relational goods to predict the trends of subjective well-being. Int. Rev. Econ. 2010, 57, 199–223. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Frank, R. The frame of reference as a public good. Econ. J. 1997, 107, 1832–1847. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Bartolini, S. Why are people so unhappy? Why do they strive so hard for money? Competing explanations of the broken promises of economic growth. In Handbook on the Economics of Happiness; Bruni, L., Porta, P.L., Eds.; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  32. Dolan, P.; Peasgood, T.; White, M. Do we really know what makes us happy? A review of the economic literature on the factors associated with subjective well-being. J. Econ. Psychol. 2007, 29, 94–122. [Google Scholar]
  33. Montero, R.; Rau, T. Relative Income and Job Satisfaction in Chile. In Handbook of Happiness Research in Latin America; Rojas, M., Ed.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  34. Duesenberry, J.S. Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1952. [Google Scholar]
  35. Ding, J.; Salinas, J.; Salinas, M.M. El Impacto de la Desigualdad de Ingresos en el Bienestar Subjetivo en China: Un Estudio Basado en la CGSS; XXVI Encuentro de Economía Pública: Oviedo, Spain, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  36. Hamilton, C. Consumerism, self-creation and prospects for a new ecological consciousness. J. Clean. Prod. 2010, 18, 571–575. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Hirsch, F. Social Limits to Growth; Routledge: London, UK, 1977. [Google Scholar]
  38. Bordieu, P. The forms of capital. In Handbook of Theory and Research for the Sociology of Education; Richardson, J., Ed.; Greenwood: New York, NY, USA, 1986. [Google Scholar]
  39. Coleman, J.S. Social capital in the creation of human capital. Am. J. Sociol. 1988, 94, S95–S120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Putnam, R. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community; Simon and Schuster: New York, NY, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  41. Esping-Andersen, G. Why We Need a New Welfare State; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  42. Becchetti, L.; Pelloni, A.; Rossetti, F. Relational goods, sociability, and happiness. Kyklos 2008, 61, 343–363. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  43. Velásquez, L. The Importance of Relational Goods for Happiness: Evidence from Manizales. Colombia. In Handbook of Happiness Research in Latin America; Rojas, M., Ed.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  44. Ryan, R.M.; Deci, E.L. On happiness and human potentials: A review of research on hedonic and eudaimonic well-being. Annu. Rev. Psychol. 2001, 52, 141–146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  45. Nussbaum, M. La Fragilidad del Bien: Fortuna y Ética en la Tragedia y la Filosofía Griega; Visor: Madrid, Spain, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  46. Gui, B.; Sugden, R. Economics and Social Interaction: Accounting for Interpersonal Relations; Gui, B., Sugden, R., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  47. Diener, E.; Oishi, S.; Lucas, R.E. Personality, culture and subjective well-being: Emotional and cognitive evaluations of life. Annu. Rev. Psychol. 2003, 54, 403–425. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  48. Easterlin, R. Towards a better theory of happiness. In Economics and Happiness: Framings of Analysis; Bruni, L., Porta, P.L., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  49. Saffer, A.J. Fostering social capital in an international multi-stakeholder issue network. Public Relat. Rev. 2019, 45, 282–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Sacco, P.L.; Vanin, P.; Zamagni, S. The economics of human relationships. In Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity; Kolm, S.-C., Mercier Ythier, J., Eds.; Elsevier North Holland: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2006; Volume 1. [Google Scholar]
  51. Klein, C. Do We Need Social Cohesion to Be Happy; Working Paper; CEPS/INSTEAD: Differdange, Luxembourg, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  52. Ferrer, D.; Giarrizzo, V. How the Economy Affects Happiness. Empirical Findings from Argentina. In Handbook of Happiness Research in Latin America; Rojas, M., Ed.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2016; pp. 193–204. [Google Scholar]
  53. Falk, R. La Globalización Depredadora. Una Crítica; Siglo XXI de España Editores: Madrid, Spain, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  54. Zamagni, S. Desarrollo sustentable: La lucha contra la pobreza y las nuevas estructuras de gobernabilidad en la era de la globalización. Revista Valores en la Sociedad Industrial 2004, 60, 16–35. [Google Scholar]
  55. Assadourian, E. Transforming cultures: From consumerism to sustainability. J. Macromarket. 2010, 30, 186–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Murtaza, N. Pursuing self-interest or self-actualitation? From capitalism to a steady-state, wisdom economy. Ecol. Econ. 2011, 70, 577–584. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Requier-Desjardins, D. El Concepto Económico de Proximidad: Impacto Para el Desarrollo Sustentable. 2017. Available online: https://goo.gl/97gTu7 (accessed on 22 November 2017).
  58. Morone, P.; Falcone, P.M.; Tartiu, V.E. Food waste valorisation: Assessing the effectiveness of collaborative research networks through the lenses of a COST action. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 238, 117868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Van den Berg, B.; Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. Monetary valuation of informal care: The well-being Valuation Method. Health Econ. 2007, 16, 1227–1244. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  60. Luechinger, S.; Raschky, P. A Valuing food disasters using the life satisfaction Approach. J. Public Econ. 2009, 93, 620–633. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Levison, A. Valuing public goods using happiness Data: The case of air quality. J. Public Econ. 2012, 96, 869–880. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Morawetz, D. Income distribution and self-rated happiness: Some empirical evidence. Econ. J. 1977, 87, 511–522. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Di Tella, R.; MacCulloch, R.J.; Oswald, A.J. Preferences over inflation and unemployment evidence from surveys of happiness. Am. Econ. Rev. 2001, 91, 335–341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Micklewright, J.; Stewart, K. Is the well-being of children converging in the European Union? Econ. J. 1999, 109, F692–F714. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Kenny, C. Does growth cause happiness, or does happiness cause growth? Kyklos 1999, 52, 3–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  66. Oswald, A.J. Happiness and economic performance. Econ. J. 1997, 107, 1815–1831. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Gerlach, K.; Stephan, G. A paper on unhappiness and unemployment in Germany. Econ. Lett. 1996, 52, 325–330. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Korpi, T. Is utility related the employment status? Employment. unemployment, labor market policies and subjective well-being among Swedish youth. Labour Econ. 1997, 4, 125–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. Income and well-being: An empirical analysis of the comparison income effect. J. Public Econ. 2005, 89, 997–1019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Frey, B.S.; Stutzer, A. Measuring preferences by subjective wel-being. J. Inst. Theor. Econ. 1999, 155, 755–778. [Google Scholar]
  71. Frey, B.S.; Stutzer, A. Happiness, economy and institutions. Econ. J. 2000, 110, 918–938. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Clark, A.E.; Oswald, A.J. Unhappiness and unemployment. Econ. J. 1994, 104, 648–659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Van Praag, B.M.S.; Frijters, P.; Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. The anatomy of subjective well-being. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2003, 51, 29–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  74. Alesina, A.; Di Tella, R.; MacCulloch, R. Inequality and happiness: Are Europeans and Americans different? J. Public Econ. 2004, 88, 2009–2042. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  75. Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A.; Gowdy, J.M. Environmental degradation and happiness. Ecol. Econ. 2007, 60, 509–516. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Wang, B.Z.; Cheng, Z. Environmental perceptions, happiness and pro-environmental actions in China. Soc. Indic. Res. 2017, 132, 357–375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Bjørnskov, C. Social capital and happiness in the United States. Appl. Res. Qual. Life 2008, 3, 43–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Rodríguez-Pose, A.; Von Berlepsch, V. Social capital and individual happiness in Europe. Bruges Eur. Econ. Res. Pap. 2012, 15, 357–386. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  79. Lee, M.S.; Ahn, C.S.Y. Anti-consumption, materialism, and consumer well-being. J. Consum. Aff. 2016, 50, 18–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Ahuvia, A.C. Consumption, Income and Happiness. In The Cambridge Handbook of Psychology and Economic Behaviour; Lewis, A., Ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  81. Mochón Morcillo, F.; Ahn, N.; De Juan, R. La felicidad de los jóvenes. Papers 2012, 97, 407–430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Stutzer, A.; Frey, B.S. Does marriage make people happy, or do happy people get married? J. Socio-Econ. 2006, 35, 326–347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  83. Grover, S.; Helliwell, J.F. How’s life at home? New evidence on marriage and the set point for happiness. J. Happiness Stud. 2019, 20, 373–390. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Figure 1. This figure shows the links between social capital and subjective well-being.
Figure 1. This figure shows the links between social capital and subjective well-being.
Sustainability 11 07102 g001
Figure 2. This figure explains the inefficiency of the neoclassic paradigm in the promotion of subjective well-being and socioeconomic and environmental sustainability.
Figure 2. This figure explains the inefficiency of the neoclassic paradigm in the promotion of subjective well-being and socioeconomic and environmental sustainability.
Sustainability 11 07102 g002
Table 1. Social, economic, and sociodemographic aspects.
Table 1. Social, economic, and sociodemographic aspects.
Primary Hypotheses
Free timeLack of trustUnfair peopleEnvironmental awarenessHigh incomeMaterialistConformists
H0: β7 ≤ 0
H1: β7 > 0
H0: β8 ≥ 0
H1: β8 < 0
H0: β9 ≥ 0
H1: β9 < 0
H0: β10 ≤ 0
H1: β10 > 0
H11: β11 ≥ 0
H11: β11 < 0
H0: β12 ≥ 0
H1: β12 < 0
H0: β13 ≥ 0
H1: β13 < 0
Secondary hypotheses
WomanAgeBasic educationMarriageChildrenHealth
H0: β1 ≤ 0
H1: β1 > 0
H0: β2 ≥ 0
H1: β2 < 0
H0: β3 ≥ 0
H1: β3 < 0
H0: β4 ≤ 0
H1: β4 > 0
H0: β5 ≤ 0
H1: β5 > 0
H0: β6 ≤ 0
H1: β6 > 0
Table 2. Variables description.
Table 2. Variables description.
2002200420062008201020122014
VariableDescriptionMeanS.DMeanS.DMeanS.DMeanS.DMeanS.DMeanS.DMeanS.D
HappinessVariable measured on a Likert scale. Take the value 0 for those people who feel very unhappy, 11 if the person was extremely happy7.301.837.321.747.631.667.631.637.571.637.571.877.421.84
Sociodemographic Aspects
Woman1, if the person surveyed was a woman, 0 otherwise0.520.490.380.480.510.500.520.490.500.500.510.500.480.50
AgeAge of respondents48.6019.2645.0918.745.8718.8746.8319.145.818.2547.6118.0148.5418.64
Basic education1, if the person surveyed claimed to have a lower level of education than secondary school; 0 otherwise0.390.480.4890.500.340.470.340.470.310.460.310.460.270.44
Marriage1, if the person surveyed was married; 0 otherwise0.560.490.5780.490.540.490.540.490.540.490.530.490.520.49
Children1, if they lived in the home with children; 0 otherwise0.390.490.4340.490.430.490.420.490.420.490.440.490.440.49
HealthVariable measured on a scale of 1 to 5. It takes the value 1 if he/she considered that their state of health was very bad, 5 if he/she considered that there state of health was very good.3.630.963.6890.873.650.903.780.933.720.923.650.923.680.93
Social aspects
Free time1, if the person surveyed claimed to meet their friends or family or every day or many times a week; 0 otherwise0.550.490.5540.490.580.490.550.490.540.490.510.500.500.50
Lack of trust1, if the respondents stated that they agree more with the fact that care must be taken with trust 1, in people; 0 otherwise0.710.450.7470.430.730.440.750.430.740.430.720.440.750.43
Unfair people1, if the respondents stated that people try to take advantage of others; 0 otherwise0.660.470.6930.460.680.460.680.460.720.440.650.470.660.47
Environmental awareness1, if the person surveyed claimed to feel concerned about the care of the environment and nature; 0 otherwise0.710.450.6900.460.820.380.760.420.780.410.810.390.780.41
Economic aspects
High income1, if the respondents claimed to have a monthly income in the home exceeding € 1500; 0 otherwise0.180.390.3590.480.330.470.210.410.330.470.310.460.310.46
Materialist1, if the respondents affirmed that it is important to have money to be able to buy expensive things; 0 otherwise0.580.490.5280.490.470.490.470.490.460.490.370.480.420.49
Conformist1, if respondents claimed to live comfortably with their income; 0 otherwise0.280.450.3660.480.320.460.260.440.320.460.240.430.290.45
Table 3. Ordered logit results.
Table 3. Ordered logit results.
2002200420062008201020122014
HappinessCoeff.S.ECoeff.S.ECoeff.S.ECoeff.S.ECoeff.S.ECoeff.S.ECoeff.S.E
Sociodemographic aspects
Woman0.090.080.000.08−0.020.080.110.070.040.08−0.120.080.19***0.08
Age−0.01 ***0.01−0.01 ***0.00−0.01 ***0.01−0.01 ***0.01−0.01 ***0.01−0.010.00−0.01 ***0.01
Basic education−0.010.110.040.100.49 ***0.11−0.060.100.100.110.42 ***0.110.32 ***0.11
Marriage0.82 ***0.100.78 ***0.110.67 ***0.100.73 ***0.080.61 ***0.100.59 ***0.100.63 ***0.09
Children−0.050.10−0.050.100.030.090.020.08−0.030.09−0.100.090.02 ***0.09
Health0.47 ***0.050.26 ***0.050.44 ***0.050.58 ***0.040.50 ***0.050.44 ***0.050.47 ***0.05
Social aspects
Free time0.62 ***0.090.52 ***0.090.49 ***0.080.66 ***0.070.46 ***0.080.51 ***0.080.43 ***0.08
Lack of trust−0.27 ***0.10−0.37 ***0.11−0.28 ***0.10−0.19 ***0.09−0.110.10−0.25 ***0.10−0.18 *0.10
Unfair people−0.32 ***0.10−0.36 ***0.10−0.29 ***0.09−0.23 ***0.08−0.24 **0.10−0.33 ***0.09−0.42 ***0.09
Environmental awareness0.48 ***0.090.40 ***0.090.46 ***0.100.37 ***0.080.34 ***0.100.27 ***0.100.120.09
Economic aspects
High income0.030.11−0.010.090.080.09−0.030.09−0.010.090.070.090.140.09
Materialist−0.24 ***0.09−0.25 ***0.09−0.18 **0.08−0.060.07−0.100.08−0.18 **0.08−0.040.08
Conformist0.32 ***0.100.40 ***0.090.44 ***0.090.57 ***0.080.32 ***0.090.46 ***0.100.40 ***0.09
cut1−4.730.65−5.190.52−4.210.51−4.570.63−4.820.65−3.260.41−3.920.44
cut2−3.330.42−4.190.41−3.600.44−2.650.35−3.710.46−2.800.37−3.210.37
cut3−2.350.35−3.480.37−2.850.38−1.500.30−2.720.37−2.170.33−2.520.33
cut4−1.520.33−2.920.35−2.130.35−0.890.29−2.190.35−1.460.31−1.730.31
cut5−0.930.32−2.450.34−1.670.340.250.28−1.510.34−0.980.30−1.250.30
cut60.140.32−1.190.33−0.510.331.070.28−0.310.32−0.020.30−0.160.30
cut70.940.32−0.470.330.190.332.220.280.400.320.660.300.510.30
cut82.150.320.620.331.430.333.810.291.560.321.700.301.540.30
cut93.350.332.100.332.840.334.900.293.160.332.900.302.840.30
cut104.300.333.120.343.980.34 4.220.3393.840.313.820.31
N1690 1632 1874 2566 1879 1884 1923
Loglikelihood−3096.17 −2934.25 −3255.23 −4334.57 −3228.30 −3469.12 −3545.21
LR chi2(12)359.07 257.56 290.18 614.77 296.65 267.69 280.06
p-value0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Note: (***), (**), (*) Statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Membiela-Pollán, M.; Alló-Pazos, M.; Pateiro-Rodríguez, C.; Blázquez-Lozano, F. The Inefficiency of the Neoclassical Paradigm in the Promotion of Subjective Well-Being and Socioeconomic, and Environmental Sustainability: An Empirical Test for the Spanish Case. Sustainability 2019, 11, 7102. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su11247102

AMA Style

Membiela-Pollán M, Alló-Pazos M, Pateiro-Rodríguez C, Blázquez-Lozano F. The Inefficiency of the Neoclassical Paradigm in the Promotion of Subjective Well-Being and Socioeconomic, and Environmental Sustainability: An Empirical Test for the Spanish Case. Sustainability. 2019; 11(24):7102. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su11247102

Chicago/Turabian Style

Membiela-Pollán, Matías, María Alló-Pazos, Carlos Pateiro-Rodríguez, and Félix Blázquez-Lozano. 2019. "The Inefficiency of the Neoclassical Paradigm in the Promotion of Subjective Well-Being and Socioeconomic, and Environmental Sustainability: An Empirical Test for the Spanish Case" Sustainability 11, no. 24: 7102. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su11247102

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop