Next Article in Journal
Treating Systemic Lupus Erythematosus (SLE): The Impact of Historical Environmental Context on Healthcare Perceptions and Decision-Making in Charleston, South Carolina
Previous Article in Journal
Differences in Lifestyle Behaviours of Students between Inner Urban and Peri-urban High Schools: A Cross-Sectional Study in Chongqing, China
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Environmental Regulation, Tenure Length of Officials, and Green Innovation of Enterprises

1
School of Accounting, Zhejiang Gongshang University, Hangzhou 310018, China
2
School of Accounting, Hebei GEO University, Shijiazhuang 050031, China
3
School of Management and E-Business, Key Research Institute-Modern Business Research Center, Zhejiang Gongshang University, Hangzhou 310018, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2020, 17(7), 2284; https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/ijerph17072284
Submission received: 16 February 2020 / Revised: 13 March 2020 / Accepted: 25 March 2020 / Published: 28 March 2020
(This article belongs to the Section Environmental Science and Engineering)

Abstract

:
Many developing countries including China are implementing increasingly stringent environmental regulations to achieve sustainable development. However, we have limited understanding about whether environmental regulations promote enterprise green innovation. To address this research gap, this study empirically analyzes the impact of environmental regulations, which is represented by the China Environmental Protection Law (2015), on enterprise green innovation, and it explores the moderating effects of official tenure on environmental regulations and corporate green innovation. The Super-Slacks-based Measure (Super-SBM) model and multiple nonlinear regression model are employed to analyze sample data of 3557 firms in China’s A-share market during the 2014–2017 period. Our results show that, in general, a higher intensity of environmental regulations is more beneficial to incentivize enterprises to implement green innovation. Meanwhile, there is an inverted U-type relationship between the tenure length of officials and green innovation of enterprises. Furthermore, the tenure length of officials plays an inverted U-shaped role in regulating the impact of environmental regulations on enterprise green innovation. Overall, this study can help us better understand the politics behind enterprises green innovation in countries like China.

1. Introduction

With the potential depletion of natural resources and the aggravation of environmental pollution, in addition to economic development, environmental protection is gradually becoming an urgent task for many countries [1]. For example, in the World Environmental Performance Rankings, launched by Yale University in the United States, China’s environmental performance index (EPI) ranked 177th out of 180 countries and regions in 2018 [2]. This ranking partly reflects China’s relatively weak environmental regulations. Therefore, China is urgently trying to improve environmental regulations in time before reaching the “threshold” of ecological environment bearing; otherwise, sustainable economic growth cannot be achieved. As a result, Chinese governments at different levels formulated and issued relatively comprehensive environmental protection policies [3]. However, the problem of environmental pollution is still serious. At the same time, many developing countries like China have relatively low social welfare level, and their goals of urbanization and industrialization are not yet achieved. This means that developing countries like China also need to achieve economic growth while implementing environmental regulations [4].
“Going green” is one of the important ways that firms adapt to realize environmental protection. Various methods of acquiring green capabilities and green practices drew increased attention and discussion in the last several decades [5,6]. In particular, green innovation is critical to achieve the “win–win” goal of environmental protection and economic development [7]. Furthermore, the relationship between local government environmental regulation and enterprise green innovation was widely studied in academic research [8]. The impacts of environmental regulation on enterprise green innovation were extensively researched, but whether there is a positive “compensation effect” or a negative “offset effect” is not agreed upon. Environmental regulations will inevitably lead to increased costs for enterprises [9,10,11]. However, some scholars believe that appropriate environmental regulations can stimulate enterprise technological innovation and gain a competitive advantage [12,13]. Through environmental regulations, the government can facilitate the green development of domestic industries and create the first-mover advantage [14], and environmental taxes can accelerate technological progress and reduce environmental pollution [15,16]. The opponents, on the other hand, do not think that regulators will do any better than entrepreneurs [17]. They argue that strict environmental regulations may be detrimental to the competitiveness of enterprises [18].
Existing research attributed the inefficiency of environmental regulations to the “race-to-the- bottom” [19] behavior of local governments in the process of environmental policy formulation and implementation. If environmental quality is included as a performance measure of officials, it is bound to affect the formulation and implementation of environmental policies. However, this hypothesis is yet to be empirically tested. In addition, in many countries, local officials still hold the decision power to allocate important resources, which will directly impact the innovation strategy of enterprises. Furthermore, in general, local officials are bound in their tenure, which can play an important role in their decision-making processes [20]. On the one hand, along with a longer tenure in office, local officials can gain more expertise and experience in formulating and implementing economic policies which are conducive to enterprise green innovation. On the other hand, as the tenure of officials becomes sufficiently long, their willingness to promote green innovation may decrease, paying more attention to issues like secure retirement.
In order to fill the gap in existing studies, we take the A-share listed companies in Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock Markets as the research sample and empirically test how the intensity of environmental regulations and the tenure of officials affect enterprise green innovation.
Our research, compared to existing studies in the literature, contributes in three major ways. Firstly, based on the Super-Slacks-based Measure (Super-SBM) model, we measure regional environmental regulations from input factors, expected output, and non-expected output. Secondly, from a macro perspective, we explore the main factors that influence enterprise innovation, environmental regulations, and the tenure length of local officials, which provides a novel way of further promoting enterprise innovation. Thirdly, we investigate the moderating effect of official tenure length on how environmental regulations impact enterprise innovation.
Overall, our study can help deepen our understanding of the important role of official tenure length in promoting environmental protection and economic development.

2. Background

As one of the largest developing countries and the second largest economy in the world, China adopted a development model characterized by relatively high investment, high resource consumption, and high pollution. This kind of economic model achieved remarkable economic development, but, at the same time, it has also hindered the sustainable development of the economy and society [21,22,23]. In 2012, China proposed the concept of an ecological civilization “that respects nature, conforms to nature, and protects nature, gives prominence to the construction of ecological civilization, integrates economic construction, political construction, cultural construction, and social construction into all aspects and the whole process, and strives for the sustainable development of China”. In 2015, a new environmental protection law, the strictest in history, came into force, calling for a modern environmental governance system featuring multi-dimensional co-governance and joint prevention and control. In the same year, the overall plan for the reform of the system of ecological civilization explicitly proposed the construction of the top-level design of the system of ecological civilization, including the system of performance evaluation and accountability for ecological civilization. Moreover, the officials of the local government shall be responsible for and evaluated by the local ecological civilization. In 2017, the Chinese government made an unprecedented determination to implement the “strictest system of ecological and environmental protection”. However, the situation of environmental pollution is still serious; thus, it is an inevitable choice to promote the innovation of an environmental management system where environmental regulations should be further improved.
The tenure of local officials is an important means for the central government. If the tenure is too short, officials are able to take quick and easy actions, which can lead to the opportunistic behavior of local firms. If the tenure is too long, local officials may lower their expectations of promotion and shirk their responsibilities. In China, the tenure for high-ranking local officials is five years. However, in practice, local officials are often transferred upon completing the five-year term. All in all, there seems to be no consistent tenure length for local officials [24]. Hence, in this paper, we aim to examine the impact of tenure length of local officials on firm behavior, especially firm innovation.

3. Theoretical Literature Review

The existing research on the impacts of environmental regulations on corporate innovation is mainly divided into two categories. The first relates to the traditional neoclassical theory. From a static perspective, it is believed that strict environmental regulations will inevitably reduce corporate profit margins, crowd out research and development (R&D) investment, and hinder corporate innovation [25]. The second category relates to the “Porter hypothesis” [12,26,27] from a dynamic perspective. It is believed that truly effective environmental regulatory policies can stimulate green technological innovation and efficiency improvements, which then accelerate innovation activities and economic growth. Furthermore, enterprises can achieve a win–win situation with high product profit and “green production”. Moreover, it was pointed out that strict environmental policies will be one of the important ways for developing countries to develop future competitive advantages [28]. In comparison, there is more research based on the “Porter hypothesis”.

4. Hypotheses Development

4.1. Environmental Regulations and Enterprise Green Innovation

The Porter hypothesis holds that environmental protection policies in the true sense will not increase the cost for enterprises. On the contrary, they can trigger innovation and generate net benefits, thus improving the international competitive advantage of enterprises [12,26,27]. On the one hand, the high intensity of environmental regulations requires enterprises to work hard to reduce pollution emissions by improving production. Enterprises usually adopt two approaches. Firstly, they control pollution level by investing in pollution control technology, which is called the “pollution control technology progress effect” of environmental regulations [29]. Secondly, they improve the productivity by improving the production technology [30]. Through technological innovation, enterprises improve the production process or improve the ability to control pollution [31]. This can eventually reduce or offset the “compliance cost” of environmental regulations and gain a competitive advantage, which is called the “innovation compensation effect” of environmental regulations. On the other hand, the government’s adoption of environmental regulations will inevitably be accompanied by certain support for technological innovation for enterprises in terms of financial policies and industrial policies. This can help solve the problem of insufficient funding for enterprise green innovation. At the same time, the implementation of environmental regulations inevitably requires the government to formulate policies conducive to environmental protection, which can incentivize enterprise green innovation. Moreover, environmental regulations can convey the signal of low resource utilization efficiency to enterprises, indicating the potential direction of technological improvement. Therefore, a reasonable environmental regulation policy can promote not only the pollution control technology, but also production technology upgrading and green innovation for enterprises. To sum up, high-intensity environmental regulations can not only incentivize enterprises to innovate and reduce pollution emission, but also result in preferential policies to reduce the capital expenses of enterprises and promote their green innovation. Based on the above analysis, the following hypothesis is proposed:
Hypothesis 1:
High-intensity environmental regulations are conducive to enterprise green innovation.

4.2. Tenure Length of Officials and Enterprise Green Innovation

Many researchers analyzed the government influence on enterprise innovation from the crowding out effect and the inducement effect, albeit with inconsistent conclusions [32,33]. They all generally agreed that the government is one of the important factors affecting enterprises innovation [34,35]. In particular, it was concluded that the relationship between tenure length of officials and technological innovation exhibits an inverted U-typed relationship [36,37,38].
A short or transitional tenure of local officials can lead to shortsightedness and lack of focus, which is not conducive to enterprise green innovation. On the other hand, if the tenure is too long, it may lead to corruption and political association. This is also not conducive to enterprise technology innovation. In some countries, each term for critical governmental posts shall not exceed a certain number of years. In general, local officials aim for reelection, reappointment, or promotion. To this end, local officials need to achieve economic growth of their regions [39]. Hence, they will endeavor to increase investment in productive projects with quick results and low risk, while reducing investment in corporate innovation activities which may be characterized by long-term cyclicality, high uncertainty, and spillover. However, with longer tenure, local officials’ enthusiasm for short-term economic growth may reduce. They may pay more attention to the quality of economic development with more technical and forward-looking innovation. Needless to say, when local officials are approaching retirement, there is less room for their promotion. Then, what is more important for them is to how to retire safely; thus, their support for enterprise green innovation activities may decrease again. In conclusion, local officials are more likely to promote enterprise innovation at moderate tenure length. However, with further extension of their tenure, they may inhibit enterprise innovation activities, as illustrated in Figure 1. Based on the analysis above, the following hypothesis is proposed:
Hypothesis 2:
There is an inverted U-shaped relationship between the tenure length of officials and the level of enterprise green innovation in their regions.

4.3. Environmental Regulations and Enterprise Green Innovation: The Moderating Effect of Tenure of Officials

Local governments usually hold great discretion for many critical resources, which can give them incentives to acquire these resources through rent-seeking. However, corporate rent-seeking behavior will increase with political stability [40]. A company needs to ensure that a local official can deliver on rent-seeking commitments during their tenure. Once the official leaves office or retires, their promises may not be fulfilled, resulting in higher risk for the company. In other words, the replacement of local officials helps restrain the rent-seeking behavior of enterprises, thus affecting the implementation of environmental regulations. Therefore, the tenure of officials may moderate the relationship between environmental regulations and enterprise green innovation. When new officials take office, they may break the interest network established by their predecessors. As the new interest network is not well established, the rent-seeking behavior of enterprises will be greatly reduced. Meanwhile, under the pressure of green gross domestic product (GDP) assessment, local officials will strictly implement environmental regulatory policies to rectify local environmental pollution problems, thereby promoting corporate green innovation. However, with further extended tenure, local officials can establish their own interest network, and rent-seeking behaviors begin to occur frequently. That is, politically connected enterprises may get preferential treatment, which will reduce their “compliance cost” for environmental regulations. Based on the above analysis, the following hypothesis is proposed:
Hypothesis 3:
There is an inverted U-shaped relationship where the tenure length of officials exerts mediation effects. That is, when the tenure length of officials is short, the promotion effect of environmental regulations on corporate innovation will be enhanced, but the mediation effect will gradually weaken with the extension of the tenure length of officials and even inhibit the promotion effect of environmental regulations on corporate innovation.

5. Research Design

5.1. Data

In this paper, we selected the enterprises in China’s A-share market, including Shenzhen Stock Exchange and Shanghai Stock Exchange, as our samples. The covering period was 2014–2017. Then, according to Tian et al. (2019), we dropped those enterprises that suffered consecutive losses (marked as ST or * ST) or where serious information was missing, in order to guarantee the stability and effectiveness of our samples. After selection, we eventually obtained 3557 enterprise samples for a total of 8991 effective observations. In order to avoid the influence of extreme values, the top and bottom of related continuous variables were reduced by 1%. Related data of environmental regulations came from China Statistical Yearbook (2015–2018). The data of the tenure of officials were sorted manually as follows: firstly, we collected data on local officials from the website of the Central People’s Government of the People’s Republic of China (home page—China overview—personnel change query) and eventually obtained the names of party secretaries in 320 cities in China from 2014 to 2017. Secondly, through the database of local government officials on the People’s Network online, we found the résumés of these local government officials. Local officials with identical names were double-checked to confirm if they were the same person. Finally, the tenure of the party secretary of each city was matched manually according to their official résumé. The data on enterprise green innovation came from the Wind database, and other relevant financial indicators and corporate governance indicators came from the China Stock Market & Accounting Research (CSMAR) database.

5.2. Variables

5.2.1. Explained Variables: Enterprise Green Innovation

For measuring enterprise green innovation, scholars proposed a variety of methods, the most widely adopted of which is based on the ratio between research and development expenditure and operating income [41,42], denoted by Innovation (INNO). A higher INNO value denotes a higher innovation level of the enterprise, and vice versa.

5.2.2. Explanatory Variables: Environmental Regulations and the Tenure of officials

(1) Environmental Regulations
In the literature, there are generally five ways to measure environmental regulations: the cost of pollution reduction [11,43]; pollution reduction [38,39]; the operating cost of pollution facilities [44] or the proportion of investment in pollution control in the total cost or output value of the enterprise; the number of industrial environmental regulations or the number of inspections and supervisions on pollution emissions by environmental regulatory agencies [45]; the ratio of GDP to energy consumption [1]. Due to the complexity of environmental policies and the different types and forms of pollutants, it is difficult to find a single index to reflect the effect of environmental regulations. Therefore, data envelopment analysis (DEA) was adopted in this study to evaluate environmental regulations.
DEA was first proposed in 1978 by American operations scientists A. Charnes, W.W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes [46]. It is a non-parametric test method developed based on the concept of relative efficiency evaluation. In DEA, the unit or organization being evaluated is called a decision-making unit (DMU). By selecting multiple input and output data of a DMU, the DEA can be categorized into five types: (1) the original Charnes-Cooper-Rhodes (CCR) model proposed in 1978 [47]; (2) the Banker-Charnes-Cooper (BCC) model which measures pure technical efficiency, that is, the ratio of technical efficiency to scale efficiency [48]; (3) the Slacks-based Measure (SEM) model which compares the efficiency among different DMUs [49]; (4) the SBM model based on relaxation variables in 2001 [50]; (5) the Super-SBM model which allows the efficiency value of effective DMU to be greater than or equal to one [51]. We employed the Super-SBM DEA model to measure environmental regulations. The Super-SBM DEA model considers undesirable outputs, which is in accordance with reality, and it is suitable for measuring the efficiency relevant to the environment. In addition, the Super-SBM DEA model overcomes the restrictions exerted by radial and piecewise linear theory. Moreover, the model can compare or sequence the decision-making units, making it feasible for input and output vectors [23,52,53].
The Super-SBM DEA model is expressed as outlined below.
Assuming there are N DMUs (decision-making units). Each unit contains three elements, namely, an input factor M, b1 expected output Ng, and b2 non-expected output Nb. We define the matrices M, Ng, and Nb as follows: M = [ m 1 , m 2 , , m n ]   R i × n ;   N g = [ n 1 g , n 2 g , n n g ]   R j × n ;   N b = [ n 1 b , n 2 b , n n b ]   R k × n . We assume that M is not empty, N g   is   not   empty ,   and   neither   is   N b . Following Färe [54], the production possibility set (P) containing the non-expected output can be constructed as
P = { ( m , n g , n b ) | m M λ , n g N g λ , n b N b λ , λ 0 } ,
where λ R n is the intensity vector. Note that Equation (1) implies constant returns to scale. Furthermore, we can modify the SBM as follows:
[ S B M ] ρ * = min 1 1 a i = 1 a s i m i 0 1 + 1 b 1 + b 2 j = 1 b 1 S j g n j 0 g + j = 1 b 2 S j b n j 0 b ,  
subject   to   m 0 = M λ + S ,   n 0 g = N g λ S g ,   n 0 b = N b λ + S b ,
S 0 , S g 0 , S b 0 , λ 0 .
In Equation (2), the vectors S = (S, Sg, Sb) are the relaxation variables of input factor M, expected output Ng, and non-expected output Nb, respectively. The value of the objective function ρ * represents DMU O ( m o , n g ,   n b ) , the value of environmental regulation. If and only if ρ o * = 1 ,   i . e . , S = 0 , S g = 0 , S b = 0 ,   DMU O ( m o , n g ,   n b ) , is the no desired output efficient. Furthermore, the results calculated based on Equation (2) are prone to multiple DMU values of one. In order to distinguish them, the DMU with ρ o * = 1 is treated as follows:
δ * = min 1 a i = 1 a m ¯ i m i 0 1 b 1 + b 2 ( j = 1 b 1 n ¯ j g n j 0 g + j = 1 b 2 n ¯ j b n j 0 b ) ,
subject   to   m ¯ j = 1 , 0 t λ j m j ,   n g ¯ j = 1 , 0 t λ j n j g ,   n b ¯ j = 1 , 0 t λ j n j b ,
m ¯ m 0 , n g ¯ n 0 g , n b ¯ n 0 b , λ 0 ,
where ρ * is defined as the environmental regulation efficiency, m denotes inputs, including industrial wastewater treatment, industrial waste gas treatment, and industrial solid waste treatment, n g represents desirable outputs, referring to the industrial output value, n b is undesirable outputs, referring to those outputs that accompany desirable outputs but are not good for enterprises or do not conform to the goals of enterprises (i.e., dust, wastewater, and general solid waste), and λ is the weight vector. Related data came from China Statistical Yearbook (2015–2018).
(2) Tenure of Officials
For measuring the tenure of officials, we used the total number of years that local officials served as the municipal party secretary. If the tenure of an official in the current year was six months or more, we counted that year; if it was less than six months, it was not counted. Particularly, if the tenure of two officials in the same year was identical, it was included in the tenure of the officials in the first half of the year. For example, official A of a city holds the post from January to June 2014, while official B holds the post from July to December of the same year as the successor. Because the government budget is usually formulated and passed in the first half of the year, and its adjustment is difficult, the year of 2014 was included in the tenure of official A.

5.3. Regression Model

To test the hypothesis we developed earlier, we constructed the following model:
I N N O = β 0 + β 1 E R + β 2 T e n u r e + β 3 T e n u r e 2 + β 4 E R × T e n u r e + β 5 E R × T e n u r e 2 + C o n t r o l + γ .
INNO is the green innovation level of enterprise, which is measured by the ratio of research and development expenditure to operating income. Based on the Super-SBM principle of DEA mentioned above, ER was calculated according to the steps listed in Table 1 to test hypothesis H1. Tenure and Tenure2 respectively represent the tenure of officials and their square, in order to investigate the impact of the tenure of officials on enterprise green innovation to test hypothesis H2. It is hypothesized that the Tenure coefficient is positive and the Tenure2 coefficient is negative. That is, in the initial period of office, with the increase of tenure, the green innovation of enterprises increases. However, when the tenure reaches a certain peak, with the increase of tenure, the green innovation of enterprises decreases. In order to test hypothesis H3, ER × Tenure and ER × Tenure2, i.e., the interaction terms of environmental regulation and tenure of official, were used to investigate the impact of tenure of officials on enterprise innovation under different environmental regulations. Specifically, at the beginning of the term of official, the tenure of office enhances the enhancement effect of environmental regulation on green innovation of enterprises; however, when the tenure exceeds a certain value, the enhancement effect of the term of office weakens or even reduces. The expected coefficient of ER × Tenure is positive, and the hypothesized coefficient of ER × Tenure2 is negative. In addition, we followed the literature and controlled other variables that may significantly impact corporate innovation, including Size, Top1, return on equity (Roe), and debt–liability ratio (Debt). Their definitions are summarized in Table 1.

6. Empirical Results and Discussion

6.1. Descriptive Statistics

The descriptive statistics of the variables are summarized in Table 2.
From Table 2, we can see that the average level of enterprise green innovation (INNO) is 0.045, which indicates that the innovation level of the samples is generally low, and the government may need to take measures to incentivize enterprises to actively carry out innovation activities. In terms of explanatory variables, the mean value of environmental regulations (ER) is 0.21, the maximum value is 2.03, and the minimum value is 0.001. This indicates that there are pronounced differences in the intensity of environmental regulations in various regions. The maximum value of tenure (Tenure) is 13, and the minimum value is one, indicating that there is a gap in tenure of officials. Its mean value is 4.36, indicating that the tenure of local municipal party secretaries is about five years. Moreover, the environmental regulations and green innovation of enterprises in 31 provinces and regions in 2014-2017are illustrated in Figure 2.
From Figure 2, it can be seen that, since the implementation of the new environmental protection law, environmental regulations and green innovation of enterprises in various provinces and regions changed, especially between 2016 and 2017. The level of enterprise green innovation is high in provinces and regions with high environmental regulation, and vice versa. In addition, the regional differences in environmental regulation are rather significant. Except for the top five provinces and regions, such as Tianjin, Beijing, and Shanghai, the efficiency of environmental regulation in other provinces is generally low.
In terms of control variables, the average enterprise size is 22.08, the maximum value is 26.11, and the minimum value is 19.91, indicating that there is a large difference in enterprise size. The average value of return on equity (Roe) is 0.07, the maximum value is 0.30, and the minimum value is −0.42, indicating that the profitability of listed companies in the sample is generally low. The average shareholding ratio of the largest shareholder (Top1) is 34.33%, the maximum is 89.09%, and the minimum is 3.39%. It can be concluded that the shareholding ratio of the largest shareholder of an enterprise is relatively scattered. The average value of debt ratio (Debt) is 0.40, which means that most enterprises will promote their development with a leverage effect. In the process of calculating the descriptive statistics, some variables were found to have extreme values, which will be dealt with in subsequent empirical research.

6.2. Correlation Test

The correlation test among variables was carried out, and the results are summarized in Table 3.
From Table 3, we can see a significant positive correlation between environmental regulation (ER) and enterprise green innovation (INNO) at the level of 1%, which preliminarily supports hypothesis H1; there is a significant positive correlation between official tenure (Tenure) and enterprise green innovation at the level of 1%. In addition, there is a significant negative correlation between enterprise size (Size) and enterprise green innovation at the level of 1%, which means that the smaller listed companies pay more attention to green innovation, possibly due to the greater survival pressure. The relationship between Roe and INNO needs further exploration. The shareholding ratio of the largest shareholder (Top1) is significantly negatively correlated with the green innovation level at the level of 1%, indicating that shareholding dispersion is not conducive to green innovation activities of enterprises. Moreover, debt is negatively correlated with INNO at the level of 1%. In brief, those correlation test results show that environmental regulations and tenure of officials can affect the level of enterprise green innovation to a certain extent. In addition, the correlation coefficients among the explanatory variables are sufficiently low, which indicates no serious multicollinearity problem in the model.
Table 4 presents the variance inflation factor (VIF) analysis for each variable. All VIF values were less than 10, which suggest that multicollinearity is not a concern.

6.3. Regression Analysis

In order to test the hypothesis developed in this paper, we conducted multiple regression based on Equation (4). The results are summarized in Table 5.
Table 5 lists the regression results on the relationships among environmental regulations, tenure length of officials, and enterprise green innovation. Column 1 shows a significant positive correlation between environmental regulations and enterprise green innovation at a significance level of p < 0.01. In other words, higher environmental regulations make it more conducive for enterprise green innovation. Therefore, hypothesis H1 is supported, which is consistent with the conclusions in the literature [59,60,61] In column 2, the regression coefficient of enterprise green innovation to the first term of tenure of is 0.001 at a significance level of p < 0.01, while the coefficient of the square term is significantly negative at a significance level of p < 0.01. Therefore, hypothesis H2 is supported. This is consistent with Reference [62]. Hence, there is an inverted U-shaped relationship between tenure length of officials and enterprise green innovation. That is, as the tenure length of officials continues to increase, the level of enterprise green innovation firstly increases and then decreases. Furthermore, our analysis reveals that the inflection point in the inverted U-shaped curve is about five years. This is a new finding. Interestingly, the average tenure of the local officials in our sample is about 4.36 years, which is less than the inflection point of the curve. This indicates that the impact of the tenure of officials on enterprise green innovation is in the upward part of the inverted U-shaped curve. In column 3, the interactive term between environmental regulations and tenure (ER × Tenure) is significantly positively correlated with enterprise green innovation at a significance level of p < 0.01. However, the interaction term between environmental regulations and the tenure (ER × Tenure2) is significantly negative at a significance level of p < 0.05. Thus, hypothesis H3 is also supported. This implies that tenure strengthens the influence of environmental regulations on enterprise innovation in the beginning. However, with increasingly longer tenure, this positive reinforcement can gradually weaken or even become negative. This may be caused by the fact that officials with short tenure are eager to highlight their achievements. Hence, they pay more attention to short-term economic growth, which is not conducive to enterprise green innovation. With longer tenure, local officials can develop richer social capital and focus on long-term economic growth through enterprise green innovation. However, if the tenure is too long, officials may be able to establish a solid social network of interest, where enterprises can obtain preferential treatment and reduce the “compliance cost” of environmental regulation policies. In this way, it can weaken or even hinder enterprise green innovation. This implies that the central government should fully consider its impact on enterprise behavior when formulating the tenure system of local officials, and it should maintain consistent policies as much as possible.
In addition, in terms of the control variables selected in column 1 to column 3, the company size (Size) and the shareholding ratio of the largest shareholder (Top1) are significantly negatively correlated with the level of enterprise green innovation at a significance level of p < 0.01, indicating that a larger scale and more dispersed equity are more detrimental to enterprise green innovation. Moreover, return on equity (Roe) is significantly negatively correlated with enterprise green innovation at a significance level of p < 0.01. In addition, the debt ratio (Debt) is significantly negatively related to the level of enterprise green innovation at a significance level of p < 0.01, which may be due to the fact that, with a higher debt ratio, indicating a greater pressure of debt repayment, an enterprise is less likely to carry out innovation activities.

6.4. Robustness Check

In this paper, we chose the DEA value calculated from Equation (2) as an alternative variable of environmental regulations and conducted the regression tests again. The results are summarized in Table 6. Based on Table 6, we can see that the regression results did not change substantially. The coefficients of the core explanatory variables are in accordance with the theoretical expectations. Furthermore, there are good levels of statistical significance, which means that the empirical results of this study are robust.

7. Summary and Conclusions

In this paper, we assessed the impact of environmental regulations and tenure of officials on enterprise green innovation. To this end, we analyzed 3557 enterprises in the A-share market for the 2014–2017 period. The Super-SBM DEA model was employed to explore environmental regulation efficiency. We examined whether environmental regulations and the tenure of officials had a negative or positive impact on enterprise green innovation. Furthermore, we also conducted robustness analyses and heterogeneity tests for our results.
We found that, in general, high-intensity environmental regulations positively influence enterprise green innovation. More specifically, there is a significant inverse U-type relationship between the tenure length of officials and enterprise green innovation. That is, as the tenure of officials increases, the level of enterprise green innovation will firstly increase until a threshold, after which it will decrease. In addition, we found that maintaining a tenure length of about five years seems the optimal level to promote green innovation. More importantly, there is an inverted U-shaped relationship when the tenure length of officials exerts mediation effects. In other words, when the tenure length of officials is short, the promotional effect of environmental regulations on corporate innovation will be enhanced. However, the mediation effect will gradually weaken when the tenure of local officials is further extended. In summary, this study can help us better understand the politics behind enterprise green innovation in countries like China.
Our empirical results also led to two policy insights. Firstly, the government can further improve environmental regulations to fully unleash the positive effects of environmental regulations on enterprise green innovation. For example, local officials can formulate financial policies to support enterprise technological innovation. Secondly, the government should set an appropriate tenure length for local officials considering the issues of environmental protection and green economy development. At the same time, the tenure system of local officials should ensure the continuity of related policies on environmental protection and green economy development. In addition, different performance appraisal and incentive policies may be required for local officials with different tenure length. This research can be extended in several ways. Firstly, a limitation of this study was our specific measurements of several variables. For example, although content analysis was used to measure environmental regulations, it may be unable to capture the actual achievement due to environmental regulations. Hence, in the future, it is necessary to further improve the measurement of environmental regulations. Secondly, our data were limited to the publicly listed companies in China. It would be interesting to examine our research in a multi-country context. Last but not the least, future research can further focus on how environmental regulations impact a specific green innovation activity like green product design [63]. Further research can also focus on analyzing the relationship between the government and enterprise innovation using analytic models [64].

Author Contributions

Conceptualization and methodology, F.W., L.F. and L.W.; formal analysis, L.W. and J.L.; writing—original draft preparation, L.F., F.W. and L.W.; writing—review and editing, F.W., J.L. and L.F.; supervision, L.W., J.L. and F.W. All authors read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Acknowledgments

This project was co-sponsored by the National Social Science Foundation of China (18BGL185 and 18CGL039) and the Zhejiang Provincial Natural Science Foundation of China (LY20G020006 and LY18G020006).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Lanoie, P.; Patry, M.; Lajeunesse, R. Environmental regulation and productivity: Testing the Porter hypothesis. J. Product. Anal. 2008, 30, 121–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Yale Center for Environmental Law & Policy, Yale University, Center for International Earth Science Information Network, Columbia University in Collaboration with the World Economic Forum. Available online: https://epi.envirocenter.yale.edu/epi-countries (accessed on 10 May 2019).
  3. Liang, Z.; Zhang, M.; Mao, Q. Improvement of eco-efficiency in China: A comparison of mandatory and hybrid environmental policy instruments. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2018, 15, 1473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  4. Wang, S.; Yao, Y.; Zhou, Y. Analysis of ecological quality of the environment and influencing factors in China during 2005–2010. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2014, 11, 1673–1693. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  5. Zhu, Q.; Sarkis, J. Relationships between operational practices and performance among early adopters of green supply chain management practices in Chinese manufacturing enterprises. Oper. Manag. 2004, 22, 265–289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Davis, C.H. The earth summit and the promotion of environmentally sound industrial innovation in developing countries. Knowl. Policy 1995, 8, 26–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Schiederig, T.; Tietze, F.; Herstatt, C. Green innovation in technology and innovation management-An exploratory literature review. R&D Manag. 2012, 42, 180–192. [Google Scholar]
  8. Du, J.; Liu, Y.; Diao, W. Assessing Regional Differences in Green Innovation Efficiency of Industrial Enterprises in China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 940. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Milani, S. The Impact of Environmental Policy Stringency on Industrial R&D Conditional on Pollution Intensity and Relocation Costs. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2017, 68, 595–620. [Google Scholar]
  10. Gray, W.B. The Cost of Regulation: OSHA, EPA and the Productivity Slow down. Am. Econ. Rev. 1987, 77, 998–1006. [Google Scholar]
  11. Gray, W.B.; Shadbegian, R.J. Plant vintage, technology, and environmental regulation. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2003, 46, 384–402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Porter, M.E.; Van, D.L. Toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness relationship. J. Econ. Perspect. 1995, 4, 97–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Hamamoto, M. Environmental regulation and the productivity of Japanese manufacturing industries. Resour. Energy Econ. 2006, 28, 299–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Simpson, D.; Bradford, R.L. Taxing variable cost: Environmental regulation as Industrial Policy. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1996, 3, 282–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Marconi, D. Trade, technical progress and the environment: The role of a unilateral green tax on consumption. Asia Pac. J. Account. Econ. 2009, 3, 297–316. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Sun, A. The establishment of the green tax policy in China-To accelerate the construction of circular economy experimental zone in Qaidam Basin of Qinghai province as an example. Asian Soc. Sci. 2013, 9, 148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Jaffe, A.B.; Stavins, R.N. Dynamic incentives of environmental regulations: The effects of alternative policy instruments on technology diffusion. J. Econ. Manag. 1995, 29, 43–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Ederington, J. Should Trade Agreements Include Environmental Policy? Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2010, 1, 84–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Konisky, D.M. Regulatory competition and environmental enforcement: Is there a race to the bottom? Am. J. Polit. Sci. 2007, 51, 853–872. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Besley, T.; Case, A. Does Electoral Accountability Affect Economic Policy Choice? Evidence from Gubernatorial Term Limits. Q. J. Econ. 1995, 110, 769–798. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Tang, K.; Kragt, M.E.; Hailu, A.; Ma, C. Carbon farming economics: What have we learned? J. Environ. Manag. 2016, 172, 49–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Wu, J.; Ma, C.; Tang, K. The static and dynamic heterogeneity and determinants of marginal abatement cost of CO2 emissions in Chinese cities. Energy 2019, 178, 685–694. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Kai, T.; Yuan, Q.; Di, Z. Does command-and-control regulation promote green innovation performance? Evidence from China’s industrial enterprises. Sci. Total Environ. 2020, 712, 13636. [Google Scholar]
  24. Shu, K.; Baoqing, P.; Lngna, Z. The political economy of the term factor in china: The term of local cadres and the behavior of local governments. China Econ. Q. 2016, 4, 893–916. [Google Scholar]
  25. Palmer, K.; Oates, W.E.; Portney, P.R. Tightening environmental standards: The benefit-cost or the no-cost paradigm. J. Econ. Perspect. 1995, 9, 119–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Porter, M.E. Toward a Dynamic Theory of Strategy. Strateg. Manag. J. 1991, S2, 95–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Porter, M.E.; Van der Linde, C. Green and competitive: Ending the statement. Harv. Bus. Rev. 1995, 73, 120–134. [Google Scholar]
  28. West, P.; Senez, P. Environmental Assessment of the North American Free Trade Agreement: The Mexican Environmental Regulation Position; The Ministry: Victoria, BC, Canada, 1992.
  29. Gray, W.B.; Shadbegian, R.J. Environmental regulation, investment timing, and technology choice. J. Ind. Econ. 1998, 46, 235–256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Dechezleprêtre, A.; Sato, M. The impacts of environmental regulations on competitiveness. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2017, 11, 183–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Stefan, A.; Mark, A.C.; Stewart, E.; Paul, L. The Porter Hypothesis at 20: Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2013, 7, 2–22. [Google Scholar]
  32. Brollo, F.; Nannicini, T.; Perotti, R.; Tabellini, G. The Political Resource Curse. Am. Econ. Rev. 2013, 103, 1759–1796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Mehlum, H.; Moene, K.; Torvik, R. Institutions and the Resource Curse. Econ. J. 2006, 116, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Manso, G. Motivating Innovation. J. Financ. 2011, 66, 1823–1860. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. González, X.; Pazó, C. Do public subsidies stimulate private R&D spending? Res. Policy 2008, 37, 371–389. [Google Scholar]
  36. Holmstrom, B. Agency Cost and Innovation. Work. Pap. Ser. 1989, 12, 305–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Baumol, W.J.; Litan, R.E.; Schramm, C.J. Sustaining entrepreneurial capitalism. Capital. Soc. 2007, 2. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Montmartin, B.; Herrera, M. Internal and External Effects of R&D Subsidies and Fiscal Incentives: Empirical Evidence Using Spatial Dynamic; Panel Model. Res. Policy 2015, 44, 1065–1079. [Google Scholar]
  39. Jones, B.F.; Olken, B.A. Do leaders matter? National leadership and growth since World War II. Q. J. Econ. 2005, 120, 835–864. [Google Scholar]
  40. Murphy, K.M.; Shleifer, A.; Vishny, R.W. Why Is Rent-Seeking So Costly to Growth? Am. Econ. Rev. 1993, 2, 409–414. [Google Scholar]
  41. Chen, Y.S.; Lai, S.B.; Wen, C.T. The Influence of Green Innovation Performance on Corporate Advantage in Taiwan. J. Bus. Ethics 2006, 67, 331–339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Cuerva, M.C.; TrigueroCano, Á.; Córcoles, D. Drivers of green and non-green innovation: Empirical evidence in Low-Tech SMEs. J. Clean. Prod. 2014, 68, 104–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Brunnermeier, S.B.; Cohen, M.A. Determinants of environmental innovation in US manufacturing industries. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2003, 2, 278–293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Rassier, D.G.; Earnhart, D. Does the Porter Hypothesis Explain Expected Future Financial Performance? The Effect of Clean Water Regulation on Chemical Manufacturing Firms. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2010, 3, 353–377. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Cole, M.A.; Elliott, R.J.R. Determining the trade–environment composition effect: The role of capital, labor and environmental regulations. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2003, 3, 363–383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Berman, E.; Bui, L.T.M. Environmental regulation and labor demand: Evidence from the South Coast Air Basin. J. Public Econ. 2001, 79, 265–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Kheder, S.B.; Zugravu, N. Environmental regulation and French firms location abroad: An economic geography model in an international comparative study. Ecol. Econ. 2012, 77, 48–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Charnes, A.; Cooper, W.W.; Rhodes, E. Measuring the efficiency of decision-making units. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 1978, 2, 429–444. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Banker, R.D.; Charnes, A.; Cooper, W.W. Some Models for Estimating Technical and Scale Inefficiencies in Data Envelopment Analysis. Manag. Sci. 1984, 30, 1078–1092. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  50. Andersen, P.; Petersen, N.C. A procedure for ranking efficient units in data envelopment analysis. Manag. Sci. 1993, 39, 1261–1264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Tone, K. A Slacks-based measure of efficiency in data envelopment analysis. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2001, 130, 498–509. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  52. Tone, K. A Slacks-based measure of super-efficiency in data envelopment analysis. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2002, 143, 32–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  53. Li, H.; Shi, J. Energy efficiency analysis on Chinese industrial sectors: An improved Super-SBM model with undesirable outputs. J. Clean. Prod. 2014, 65, 97–107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Färe, R.; Grabowski, R.; Grosskopf, S.; Kraft, S. Efficiency of a fixed but allocatable input: A non-parametric approach. Econ. Lett. 1997, 56, 187–193. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Wang, F.Z.; Chen, F.Y. Board governance, environmental regulation and green technology innovation—Based on the empirical test of listed companies in heavy pollution industries in China. Sci. Res. 2018, 36, 361–369. [Google Scholar]
  56. Ali, R.; Sial, M.S.; Brugni, T.V.; Hwang, J.; Khuong, N.V.; Khanh, T.H.T. Does CSR Moderate the Relationship between Corporate Governance and Chinese Firm’s Financial Performance? Evidence from the Shanghai Stock Exchange (SSE) Firms. Sustainability 2020, 12, 149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  57. Yu, L.C.; Zhang, W.G.; Bi, Q. Will environmental taxes force companies to innovate green? Audit. Econ. Res. 2019, 2, 79–90. [Google Scholar]
  58. Sial, M.S.; Chunmei, Z.; Khuong, N.V. Do female and independent directors explain the two-way relationship between corporate social responsibility and earnings management of Chinese listed firms? Int. J. Account. Inf. Manag. 2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Yang, C.H.; Tseng, Y.H.; Chen, C.P. Environmental Regulations, Induced R&D, and Productivity: Evidence from Taiwan’s Manufacturing Industries. Resour. Energy Econ. 2012, 4, 514–532. [Google Scholar]
  60. Sen, S. Corporate governance, environmental regulations, and technological change. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2015, 80, 36–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Guo, L.L.; Qu, Y.; Tseng, M.L. The interaction effects of environmental regulation and technological innovation on green growth performance. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 162, 894–902. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Li, H.J.; Zhang, Z.Y. Local official tenure, corrupting and firm R&D investment. Stud. Sci. Sci. 2014, 5, 744–757. [Google Scholar]
  63. Zhang, Y.; Hafezi, M.; Zhao, X.; Shi, V. The impact of development cost on product line design and its environmental performance. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2017, 194, 126–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Ji, Y.; Qu, S.J.; Wu, Z.; Liu, Z. A Fuzzy-Robust Weighted Approach for Multicriteria Bilevel Games. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform. 2020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The relationship between the tenure length of officials and enterprise green innovation.
Figure 1. The relationship between the tenure length of officials and enterprise green innovation.
Ijerph 17 02284 g001
Figure 2. The environmental regulations and green innovation of enterprises in China in 2014–2017.
Figure 2. The environmental regulations and green innovation of enterprises in China in 2014–2017.
Ijerph 17 02284 g002
Table 1. Variable definitions. R&D—research and development
Table 1. Variable definitions. R&D—research and development
Variable TypesVariablesDefinitions and MeasurementsLiterature
Explained variableINNOR&D expenditure/revenue[41,42]
Explanatory variablesER(1) Environmental regulation (ER) index, i.e., the calculation method in Section 5.2.2.(1);
(2) Ranking the DEA value in order from large to small;
(3) Taking the reciprocal of the order;
(4) Returning the reciprocal as the valve of environmental regulation.
[55]
TenureThe tenure of an official calculated as described in Section 5.2.2.(2)
Tenure2The square of the number of years an official held office
ER × TenureInteraction between environmental regulation and tenure of officials
ER × Tenure2Square interaction term between environmental regulation and the tenure of officials
Control variablesSizeTotal assets at the end of the natural logarithm[4,23,56]
Top1The shareholding ratio of the largest shareholder[57]
RoeNet profit/average net assets[4,58]
DebtTotal liabilities at end/total assets at end[57,58]
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of variables.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of variables.
VariablesObservationsMeanSDMinMax
INNO89910.04480.04360.00300.2544
ER89910.21210.41160.00102.0331
Tenure89914.36253.01381.000013.0000
Size899122.07671.270419.912926.1053
Roe89910.06660.0955−0.42230.3029
Top1899134.332914.74113.3989.09
Debt89910.39660.19810.05520.8719
Table 3. Correlation coefficients of main variables.
Table 3. Correlation coefficients of main variables.
VarINNOERTenureSizeRoeTop1Debt
INNO1.00000.0616 ***0.0853 ***−0.3596 ***0.0308 ***−0.1649 ***−0.3605 ***
ER0.0932 ***1.00000.1943 ***−0.01060.0054 *0.0282 ***−0.0150
Tenure0.1047 ***0.1947 ***1.00000.0296 ***0.00360.01190.0110
Size−0.2824 ***0.0614 ***0.0418 ***1.00000.01240.1012 ***0.5562 ***
Roe−0.0249 **0.0039−0.00560.0190 *1.00000.1391 ***−0.1035 ***
Top1−0.1681 ***0.0466 ***0.01120.1574 **0.1063 ***1.00000.0684 ***
Debt−0.3163 ***−0.00550.01040.5656 ***−0.1741 **0.0782 ***1.0000
Note: the upper right part of the table shows the Spearman test, and the lower left part shows the Pearson test. ***, **, and * respectively represent statistical significance levels of 1%, 5%, and 10%.
Table 4. Variance inflation factor (VIF) statistics. Mean VIF: 1.21.
Table 4. Variance inflation factor (VIF) statistics. Mean VIF: 1.21.
VariableVIFER
ER1.050.955822
Tenure1.040.961085
Size1.530.652039
Roe1.070.938797
Top11.040.963473
Debt1.550.644229
Table 5. Regression coefficients.
Table 5. Regression coefficients.
Variable(1)(2)(3)
ER0.0002 ***
(4.107)
Tenure 0.001 ***
(6.565)
Tenure2 −0.0001 ***
(−2.547)
ER × Tenure 0.00005 ***
(7.296)
ER × Tenure2 3.82 × 10−6 **
(−2.060)
Size−0.001 ***
(−3.781)
−0.002 ***
(−4.100)
−0.002 ***
(−4.303)
Roe−0.034 ***
(−8.393)
−0.033 ***
(−8.142)
−0.033 ***
(−8.314)
Top1−0.0002 ***
(-6.264)
−0.0002 ***
(−6.270)
−0.0002 ***
(−6.499)
Debt−0.046 ***
(-19.481)
−0.046 ***
(−19.636)
−0.046 ***
(−19.406)
Ind/YearYesYesYes
Constant0.092 ***
(2.631)
0.085 ***
(2.414)
0.089 **
(2.538)
Observations899189918991
F68.9968.7969.10
R-squared0.39710.39920.4003
Note: The standard error of each estimated value is provided in brackets; *** represents p < 0.001, ** represents p < 0.05.
Table 6. Regression coefficients for the robustness check model.
Table 6. Regression coefficients for the robustness check model.
Variable(1)(2)(3)
ER0.005 ***
(5.306)
Tenure 0.001 ***
(6.565)
Tenure2 −0.0001 ***
(−2.547)
ER × Tenure 0.001 ***
(2.971)
ER × Tenure2 0.0003
(1.319)
Size−0.002 ***
(−4.107)
−0.002 ***
(−4.100)
−0.002 ***
(−4.350)
Roe−0.033 ***
(−8.282)
−0.033 ***
(−8.142)
−0.033 ***
(−8.184)
Top1−0.0002 ***
(−6.355)
−0.0002 ***
(−6.270)
−0.0002 ***
(−6.447)
Debt−0.046 ***
(−19.423)
−0.046 ***
(−19.636)
−0.046 ***
(-19.334)
Ind/YearYesYesYes
Constant0.091 ***
(2.597)
0.085 ***
(2.414)
0.093 ***
(2.668)
Observations899189918991
F69.2168.7968.83
R-squared0.39780.39920.3993
Note: The standard error of each estimated value is provided in brackets; *** represents p < 0.001.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, F.; Feng, L.; Li, J.; Wang, L. Environmental Regulation, Tenure Length of Officials, and Green Innovation of Enterprises. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2020, 17, 2284. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/ijerph17072284

AMA Style

Wang F, Feng L, Li J, Wang L. Environmental Regulation, Tenure Length of Officials, and Green Innovation of Enterprises. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2020; 17(7):2284. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/ijerph17072284

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Fan, Lili Feng, Jin Li, and Lin Wang. 2020. "Environmental Regulation, Tenure Length of Officials, and Green Innovation of Enterprises" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 17, no. 7: 2284. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/ijerph17072284

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop