Next Article in Journal
Do Energy Resource Curse and Heterogeneous Curse Exist in Provinces? Evidence from China
Next Article in Special Issue
Effect of Oil Prices on Exchange Rate Movements in Korea and Japan Using Markov Regime-Switching Models
Previous Article in Journal
Design and Analysis on an Optimized Interface Algorithm for Real-Time Integrated Simulation System of Renewable Energy and the Power Grid
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Effects of Oil and Gas Risk Factors on Malaysian Oil and Gas Stock Returns: Do They Vary?
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Dynamic Spillover and Hedging among Carbon, Biofuel and Oil

1
Institute of Economics and International Trade, Pusan National University, Busan 46241, Korea
2
Department of Economics, Pusan National University, Busan 46241, Korea
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Submission received: 27 July 2020 / Revised: 16 August 2020 / Accepted: 23 August 2020 / Published: 25 August 2020
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Time Series Analysis of Energy Economics)

Abstract

:
In recent years, there has been growing interest in the market interactions between carbon (or clean/renewable energy) and traditional fossil energy such as coal and oil, but few studies have discussed their dynamic volatility spillover and time-varying correlation. To investigate these issues, we used the weekly data of the European Union carbon emission allowance (EUA) futures, biofuel and Brent oil prices from 25 October 2009 to 5 July 2020. We employed the vector autoregressive-generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (VAR-GARCH) model with the Baba, Engle, Kraft and Krone (BEKK) specification. Our main findings are summarized as follows: First, we identified the sudden changes and the volatility persistence in the EUA, biofuel, and Brent oil markets, and also confirmed that the volatility of the markets has changed significantly over time. Second, we found a weak volatility spillover effect among the three markets, and a strong spillover effect between the EUA and Brent oil markets. In particular, the effect of volatility spillover from the Brent oil market to the EUA market was the strongest than the other cases. Lastly, in financial market, by holding the EUA and energy sources together as assets, investors can effectively hedge their investment risk. The possibility of hedging is more pronounced between the EUA and biofuel markets.

Graphical Abstract

1. Introduction

The carbon market under the European Union (EU) emission trading system (ETS), which was opened in 2005 to tackle global climate change caused by greenhouse gas emissions, has been developing rapidly. Although the carbon market is an emerging market, it has become more essential in the global commodity and financial markets, in which investors can make profits and diversify or hedge their portfolio risks [1,2]. However, in recent years, as we will see later, there have been large fluctuations and some big sudden changes in the movement of the EU carbon emission allowance (EUA) prices. The movement is closely connected to the prices of fossil and clean/renewable energies primarily for three reasons: First, the association of fossil energy combustion with increased carbon emissions has been proven, and lower fossil energy prices can lead to higher energy consumption, which can cause in turn a rise in demand for carbon credits and a rise in carbon prices. However, if fossil energy price decreases due to lower production activity, then the decrease in the use of fossil fuel can lower the demand for carbon credits and the carbon price. Second, the growing global population and the steady economic growths led by the major developing countries have significantly increased fossil energy consumption, resulting in increased carbon emissions and higher carbon prices. Third, clean/renewable energy can substitute fossil energy and decrease carbon emissions from fossil energy combustion (the difference in energy use sensitivity due to seasonal and weather changes also can affect the volatility of carbon price and fossil and clean/renewable energy prices [3,4]).
The relationship between carbon (and clean/renewable energy) and fossil energy prices is of interest to the various economic players from the following two aspects: First, the potential pollutant emission source (heavy energy-using companies such as power stations and industrial plants) are trying to reduce greenhouse gas emission (recently, greenhouse gas reduction is one of the major achievements of the environmental management system (EMS) [5,6]). The government policy for reducing carbon emissions and the price volatility of carbon could influence the operations and related stock market performance of industries covered by the EU ETS [7,8]. Therefore, the industrial sectors and its participants want sufficient information on carbon (and clean/renewable energy) and fossil energy prices to pursue their efficient way of using energy and optimal strategies for carbon emission reduction. Second, with the advent of the carbon credit market, the connectivity between the financial and carbon (or energy) markets has been strengthened, and the relationship between these asset markets has become closer. Hence, it becomes more important for policy makers and market participants to fully grasp the structure of the linkages between the carbon and financial markets.
Based on the above reasons and needs, there are ample incentives to study the connectedness between carbon prices and energy source-specific prices (i.e., fossil and clean/renewable energy prices). However, we have confirmed that so far, few studies have analysed the time-varying correlation and the spillover of dynamic volatility among the three markets. The purpose of our study is thus to uncover the dynamic spillover and hedging among carbon (the EUA), clean/renewable energy (biofuel) and fossil energy (Brent crude oil) prices. For this aim, we employ the vector autoregressive-generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (VAR-GARCH) model with the Baba, Engle, Kraft and Krone (BEKK) specification of the weekly price data in these three markets.
The contributions of our study are three fold: First, we analyse these relationships by applying a trivariate framework. Although there are many studies on the market connectedness among carbon, biofuel and crude oil, all these studies focus on their bivariate relationships. Second, although the price dynamics of the three markets are volatile and show sudden changes, few studies have considered these sudden changes in their analysis. We incorporate explicitly the effect of a sudden change in the analysis. Third, although the EUA is regarded as an important financial asset in reality, no study analysed its optimal weight in the portfolio and hedging ability. We regard the EUA as one of financial asset and study optimal weight in the portfolio and hedging ability of the investment decision.
The rest of this study is laid out as follows: Section 2 provides a theoretical and empirical review of the previous literature. Section 3 displays the sample data and methodology employed in our analysis. Section 4 presents the main findings of our empirical analysis. Section 5 provides the conclusions of this study.

2. Literature Review

The mainstream of research on the EUA trading market is that the carbon market is closely related with fossil energy markets [9,10,11,12]. This is mainly explained for the following two reasons: First, the ratio of fossil energy is about 80% of global energy consumption, and the combustion of fossil energy is known to be a major source of global carbon emissions [13]. In particular, fossil energy has been used as a primary fuel for power generation companies, and carbon prices are considered a major cost for the EU electric power companies. Thus, the EUA price is regarded as a cost of heavy energy-using companies, and fluctuation of the EUA price can lead to the volatility of fossil energy markets.
Among others, Nazifi and Milunovich [12] explored the linkage between the EUA price and the prices of coal, natural gas, electricity and oil. They found short-run linkages between carbon and other energy prices but did not discover any long-term relationship between them. Chevallier [14] found evidence that an interaction exists between the price of carbon and the dynamics of macroeconomic activity (industrial production) and price by energy source (oil, natural gas and coal). Balcılar et al. [15] uncovered the risk spillover between energy and the EUA prices and found that a substantial time-varying risk transfer from the energy market to the carbon market. Ortas and Álvarez [16] confirmed that carbon assets and energy commodities exhibit varying lead/lag movements at different time frequencies and argued that higher costs for pollution activities would be an incentive for companies to implement their environmental industrial processes. Zhang and Sun [17] pointed out that a unidirectional spillover of volatility from the coal market to the carbon market, and from the carbon market to the natural gas market. They found that the positive linkage between the carbon and fossil energy markets has become apparent over time. Dhamija et al. [18] investigated the volatility co-ordination between the EUA market and the energy market (oil, natural gas and coal), and found evidence of a small but significant volatility transition from the energy market to the EUA market. Ji et al. [19] revealed that the price of Brent oil is an important element influencing the EUA price fluctuations and risks, and there is feedback from the carbon market to other energy-related markets. Uddin et al. [20] found evidence that carbon assets provide diversification benefits for energy asset investments. Chevallier et al. [21] investigated the interdependence structure between the EUA and major energy prices and found that carbon prices co-move weakly with energy prices, and their link to oil and gas prices is negative. Wu et al. [22] researched the volatility spillover effect between carbon and traditional fossil energy markets. They displayed that the cost of carbon emissions promotes the use of clean energy, and the spillover of volatility between the carbon emissions market and the coal (oil) market is the strongest (weakest).
In particular, the volatility of coal price is known to be the most important factor influencing the changes in carbon price [10]. For instance, Castagneto-Gissey [23] argued that the coal price affects the electricity price, which is a factor causing a bidirectional causal linkage between the price of carbon and electricity. Hammoudeh et al. [24] revealed a negative linkage between coal and the EUA prices, that is, increasing coal prices could lead to a carbon price decrease. Also, Hammoudeh et al. [25] argued that in the short term, the period of decreasing in coal prices had greater influence on carbon prices than the period of increasing in coal prices.
Second, as natural gas is an important source of power generation in Europe, the price and volatility of natural gas can influence the carbon emission demand from energy-intensive companies, leading to changes in carbon prices and its volatility. For instance, Fezzi and Bunn [26] identified the interaction among energy source prices in the UK and discovered that gas prices have a significant influence on carbon prices, both of which affect electricity prices. Hammoudeh et al. [27] uncovered the impact of changes in energy (oil, coal, natural gas and electricity) prices on the carbon prices in the U.S. They found that when carbon prices are very low, changes in the natural gas price negatively affect the carbon prices.
Clean energy markets are also closely connected to the EUA and fossil energy markets. The purchase of carbon emission credits will lead to higher costs, especially for companies in heavy energy-consuming industries. For profit, companies will make countermeasures to reduce carbon emission costs. The switch to biofuels has been promoted within the EU not only because it helps to reduce greenhouse gas emissions, but also because it strengthens energy security by lowering foreign dependence on fossil fuels [28]. Ajanovic and Haas [29] pointed out that in the early 2000s, there were expectations that biofuels would decrease greenhouse gas emissions and replace fossil fuels in the transportation sector. However, in reality, such expectations were not realized. The authors described the major barriers to the expansion of biofuels: the relatively higher cost and moderate environmental performance compared to fossil fuels, the constraints on feedstock, and the competition as a food source. Reboredo [30] investigated the spillover of volatility between the oil market and the EUA market during Phase II of the EU ETS and found that there was no evidence of significant volatility spillover effect between the two markets. Wise et al. [31] explained that the increase of biofuels usage could reduce the use of traditional fossil oil, consequently reducing CO2 emissions. This suggests the carbon price is positively linked to biofuel price. Chiu et al. [32] also argued that the use of biofuels has been expanded not only to reduce carbon emissions, but also to alleviate the negative influence of fluctuating oil prices. In other words, the incentive to use biofuels is that they release relatively less carbon than fossil energy sources. Chao et al. [33] argued that applying carbon emission policies to airlines could lead to a transition to biofuels in the aviation sector in the U.S. Chen et al. [34] showed that after the global financial crisis of 2008, the correlation among the EUA, natural gas and coal markets has weakened, but their volatility has increased.
Clean energy, including biofuel, is an alternative energy source and a substitute of fossil energy [35,36,37]. Thus, if the EUA price is very high, the energy consumers can reduce their preference for fossil energy and increase the use clean energy, which can lead to increase the clean energy price. Similarly, the volatility of the EUA and clean energy prices could change in the same direction. Dutta [38] showed that in recent years, the ethanol production in Brazil has increased significantly to reduce the carbon emissions and the reliance on the fossil fuels.
A substitute effect of energy sources can be more pronounced in the long-run. If low-carbon power sources such as wind and solar power become more economical and widely available, these changes could reduce the demand for fossil fuels and lower the EUA prices. Especially, the biofuel production has significantly grown over the past decade to mitigate the adverse effects of carbon emissions [39]. Nevertheless, there are few studies on the relationship between clean energy, including biofuels, and the EUA prices. We think this is because the biofuels and the EUA markets are relatively emerging and immature market. Dutta [39] analysed the relationship between the EUA and the biodiesel markets and found a significant transfer of risk from the carbon market to the biodiesel market. This suggests that the fluctuations in carbon prices may increase the uncertainty in the biodiesel prices. He also found that a rise in the price of carbon emission credits leads to increase the price of biodiesel feedstock.
There is not much research on the interdependence between biofuels and crude oil. For example, Chang and Su [40] found that the significant price transfer effect of crude oil to biofuel futures, and the substitute of biofuels for fossil fuels during the periods of high oil prices. Serra et al. [41] analysed the Brazilian ethanol industry and discovered a strong connectedness between the food and energy markets in the level and volatility of prices. They also found that because the ethanol producers regard oil as a substitute, the price increase induced in the oil market has spread to the renewable fuels market in Brazil. Serra et al. [42] found the long-run relationships among ethanol, oil, gasoline, and corn prices. Chiu et al. [32] investigated the relationships among ethanol, crude oil, and corn prices. They revealed the long-run causal connectivity among these three market prices, and also found the short-run causality from fossil energy (oil) price to biofuel (ethanol) price. Hossain and Serletis [43] showed that there is a small but statistically significant possibility of substitution between biofuels and natural gas, as well as between biofuel and oil when the prices of fossil fuels changes.
As shown above, although there are some studies on the relationships among carbon, biofuel and crude oil, all these studies focus on the bivariate relationship. Meanwhile, we analyse these relationships by applying trivariate framework. Analysis using the trivariate GARCH model is very few, moreover, we can find only two studies which use the trivariate GARCH model with sudden change dummies, namely those by Miralles-Marcelo et al. [44] and Jiao et al. [45]. These two papers did not focus their research on energy markets. In this respect, we can contribute energy finance literature by broadening the methodology for analysis of the price relationship among energy markets.

3. Data and Methodology

3.1. Sample Data

For the empirical analysis, we used weekly closing price data for the EUA, biofuel, and Brent oil markets. We obtained the EUA data from Investing.com (https://www.investing.com), and biofuel (S&P GSCI Biofuel Index) and Brent oil data (S&P GSCI Brent Crude Index) from Yahoo! Finance (https://finance.yahoo.com). The sample period is from 25 October 2009 to 5 July 2020. Figure 1 displays the fluctuation of the weekly prices and the logarithmic returns of each series, which show some significant sudden changes in the return series of all markets.
Panel A of Table 1 introduces the descriptive statistics of the weekly returns for the three markets. During the sample period, the average returns of the EUA are positive, while those of biofuel and Brent oil are negative. As shown in the standard deviation, the EUA is found to be the most volatile market, while biofuel is the least volatile. Regarding the non-normality features, all returns data displayed asymmetry and leptokurtic distributions with higher peaks and thicker tails than the normal distribution.
Therefore, the Jarque-Bera test statistics are not consistent with the aforementioned features of the Gaussian distribution, indicating a non-linear process. The Ljung-Box Q test statistics show that there is a serial correlation of the returns and squared returns for most series. The ARCH effect is found in all return series. This means that the GARCH-class model can fit well into these return series well.
Panel B of Table 1 summarizes the results of three types of unit root test. The augmented GLS-detrended Dickey-Fuller (DF-GLS) test of Elliott et al. [47], the PP test of Phillips and Perron [48], and the KPSS test of Kwiatkowski et al. [49]. The resulting values from the DF-GLS and PP tests are large and negative, rejecting the null hypothesis of the unit root at the 1% level of significance. The KPSS test statistics do not reject the null hypothesis for stationarity at the 1% level of significance. Thus, all series of the returns studied in the analysis can be said to be stationary processes.

3.2. Methodology

We assume the data generating process of the returns series considered in this study is an autoregressive (AR) process to order one. This indicates that the dynamics of the conditional mean of the return series can be explained using the previous value as follows:
r t = μ + ϕ r t 1 + ϵ t   with   ϵ t = z t h t ,     z t ~ N ( 0 , 1 )
where | μ | [ 0 , ) ,   | ϕ | < 1 , and h t is the conditional variance of the series.

3.2.1. Univariate Model: AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) Model

We also assume the dynamics of conditional variance of returns can be described by the GARCH(1,1) model of Bollerslev [50] as follows:
h t = ω + α ϵ t 1 2 + β h t 1
where ω > 0 , α 0 , and β 0 for the non-negativity of variance. The persistence of conditional variance in the equation is measured as the sum of parameters ( α + β ) . If the sum of parameters ( α + β ) is quite close to 1, the shock on the conditional variance is infinitely persistent.

3.2.2. The ICSS Algorithm

To determine the number of sudden changes in variance of the returns and when each variance shift occurs, we employ the ICSS algorithm [51]. The major assumption of this algorithm is that until a sudden change happens as the consequence of an event, the variance is stationary over the initial period. Then the variance of series remains as a stationary state until another shock occurs.
Let’s assume that a time series { ϵ t } has a mean of zero and an unconditional variance of σ t 2 . The variances in intervals are given by σ j 2 , j = 0 ,   1 , , N T , where N T is the total number of variance changes in T observations, and 1 < k 1 < k 2 < < k N T < T are the set of change points. The variance over the N T intervals is defined as follows:
σ t 2 = [ σ 0 2 1 < k < k 1 σ 1 2 k 1 < k < k 2 σ N T 2 k N T < k < T
From the first observation to the k t h time point, the cumulative sum of squares can be expressed as follows:
C k = t = 1 k ϵ t 2 , k = 1 , 2 , , T
Let’s define the statistic D k as follows:
D k = ( C k C T ) , D 0 = D T = 0
where C T is the sum of squared residuals from the sample period of time.
If no change in variance occurs, the D k statistic oscillates around zero (while the D k is plotted against k , similar to a horizontal line). While, if one or more changes of variance happen, the D k statistic moves up or down from zero. Under the null hypothesis of constant variance, we use the critical values calculated from the distribution of D k to identify significant changes in variance. If the maximum absolute value of D k exceeds the critical value, we can reject the null hypothesis of homogeneity. When we define k * as the value at which max k | D k | is reached, and if max k ( T / 2 ) | D k | is greater than the critical value, then k * can be called as the time point at which the change in variance of the series happens. And the term ( T / 2 ) is to standardize the distribution. At the 95th percentile of the asymptotic distribution of max k ( T / 2 ) | D k | , the critical value is 1.358. So, the upper and lower bounds can be set to ± 1.358 on the D k plot. Points of change in variance are detected when these bounds are exceeded [51,52].
The GARCH(1,1) model with sudden changes can be written as follows:
h t = ω + δ 1 D 1 + + δ n D n + α ϵ t 1 2 + β h t 1
where D 1 ,   ,   D n denote dummy variables representing sudden changes in volatility, which is identified by the ICSS algorithm. During the period of sudden change, the value of dummy variable becomes one; otherwise zero.

3.2.3. Trivariate Model: VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1) Model with BEKK Specification

Using the VAR(1) process, we assume the conditional mean of returns series can be described as follows:
r 1 , t = c 1 + a 11 r 1 , t 1 + a 12 r 2 , t 1 + a 13 r 3 , t 1 + ϵ 1 , t
r 2 , t = c 2 + a 21 r 1 , t 1 + a 22 r 2 , t 1 + a 23 r 3 , t 1 + ϵ 2 , t
r 3 , t = c 3 + a 31 r 1 , t 1 + a 32 r 2 , t 1 + a 33 r 3 , t 1 + ϵ 3 , t
ϵ i , t | Ω t 1 ~ N ( 0 ,   H t )
where r i , t is the weekly returns of three markets at time t ( r 1 , t = EUA, r 2 , t = Biofuel, r 3 , t = Brent oil). c i and a i j are parameters to be estimated. The random error ϵ i , t stands for the innovation of each market at time t using the corresponding ( 3 × 3 ) conditional variance-covariance matrix H t , and Ω t 1 is the set of information available at time ( t 1 ) .
The conditional variance-covariance matrix of trivariate framework of the BEKK parameterization [5] can be presented as follows:
H t = C C + A ϵ t 1 ϵ t 1 A + B H t 1 B
where C represents a ( 3 × 3 ) lower triangular matrix with six parameters. A denotes a ( 3 × 3 ) square matrix of parameters, which measures the degree to which the conditional variance is affected by the squared errors of past or the shock of events on the volatility. B is a ( 3 × 3 ) square matrix of parameters and represents the degree to which the current conditional variance level is affected by the past conditional variances. The off-diagonal elements of matrices A and B capture the cross-market effects between the two markets; shock spillover ( α 12 , α 13 , α 21 , α 23 , α 31 and α 32 ) and volatility spillover ( β 12 , β 13 , β 21 , β 23 , β 31 and β 32 ).
The conditional variance-covariance matrix of trivariate GARCH-BEKK model can be written as follows:
H t = [ c 11 0 0 c 21 c 22 0 c 31 c 32 c 33 ] [ c 11 c 21 c 31 0 c 22 c 32 0 0 c 33 ] + [ α 11 α 12 α 13 α 21 α 22 α 23 α 31 α 32 α 33 ] ϵ t 1 ϵ t 1 [ α 11 α 21 α 31 α 12 α 22 α 32 α 13 α 23 α 33 ] + [ β 11 β 12 β 13 β 21 β 22 β 23 β 31 β 32 β 33 ] H t 1 [ β 11 β 21 β 31 β 12 β 22 β 32 β 13 β 23 β 33 ] ,   ϵ t 1 ϵ t 1 = [ ϵ 1 , t 1 2 ϵ 1 , t 1 ϵ 2 , t 1 ϵ 1 , t 1 ϵ 3 , t 1 ϵ 2 , t 1 ϵ 1 , t 1 ϵ 2 , t 1 2 ϵ 2 , t 1 ϵ 3 , t 1 ϵ 3 , t 1 ϵ 1 , t 1 ϵ 3 , t 1 ϵ 2 , t 1 ϵ 3 , t 1 2 ] ,   H t = [ h 11 , t h 12 , t h 13 , t h 21 , t h 22 , t h 23 , t h 31 , t h 32 , t h 33 , t ]
By incorporating the sudden change dummies, Equation (11) can be rewritten as follows:
H t = C C + A ϵ t 1 ϵ t 1 A + B H t 1 B + k = 1 n D k X k X k D k
where D denotes a ( 3 × 3 ) diagonal parameter matrix; X denotes a ( 1 × 3 ) row vector of volatility of the sudden change dummy variables taking a value of 1 from each point of the sudden change of variance onwards and zero elsewhere; n is the number of sudden change points.
The trivariate GARCH-BEKK model can be estimated with the optimized maximum likelihood estimation method. The conditional function of log likelihood L ( θ ) can be written as follows:
L ( θ ) = T l n ( 2 π ) 1 2 t = 1 T ( l n | H t ( θ ) | + ϵ t ( θ ) H t 1 ( θ ) ϵ t ( θ ) )
where θ is the vector of the unknown parameters to be estimated.

3.2.4. Cost Minimizing Portfolio and Dynamic Hedging Ratio

The conditional variance and covariance of the return series is the basic data commonly used in the asset pricing, the investment risk management, and the portfolio allocation. Kroner and Ng [53] proposed a method to calculate the risk-minimized portfolio without reducing the expected returns. If the portfolio with zero expected returns is composed of two assets ( i ,   j ) , the optimal portfolio weight of the holdings of asset i , w i j , t * is given as follows:
w i j , t = h j j , t h i j , t h i i , t 2 h i j , t + h j j , t
w i j , t * = 0   i f   w i j , t < 0 ; w i j , t * = w t i j   i f   0 w i j , t 1 ; w i j , t * = 1   i f   w i j , t > 1
where h i i , t and h j j , t are the conditional volatility of the i and j market, respectively. h i j , t is the conditional covariance between the two markets at time t . The optimal portfolio weight of the j market is equal to ( 1 w i j , t * ) in the budget constraint.
In this study, we also calculate the risk-minimized hedge ratio or the optimal hedge ratio, β , following the methodology of Kroner and Sultan [54]:
β i j , t = h i j , t h j j , t
This ratio means that in order to minimize the risk of a portfolio, which is the $1 long position (position to hold) on the i asset, the investor should take the $ β short position (position not to hold) on the j asset.

4. Empirical Results

4.1. Detection of Sudden Changes in Conditional Variance

Using the ICSS algorithm, we calculate the standard deviations between the time points to detect the sudden changes in variance. As shown above, Figure 1b,d,f display the movements of returns of the EUA, biofuel and Brent oil series, and the dotted lines show the points of sudden change with the band of ±3 standard deviations. Table 2 summarizes the sub-periods of sudden volatility changes detected by the ICSS algorithm. All the series returns have the sudden change points corresponding to the distinct regimes of volatility.
These sudden changes can be due to geopolitical factors and economic, political and global shocks in these markets (It is very cautious to mention some specific events because the sudden change happens due to the overlapping of many different factors. Nevertheless, it is possible to mention several events for the energy sector; The plunge in international oil prices in 2012 may be attributed to the fact that major oil producing countries did not agree to control oil production, despite declining oil demand due to the global economic downturn that has continued since 2008. Since 2014, oversupply of the global oil market and market restructuring have been underway due to the increase in oil production in non-OPEC countries centered on the U.S. called the shale revolution. From the beginning of 2020, most of the world’s economy has been stagnant and stiff due to the COVID-19 pandemic, and energy demand has also significantly decreased). We generate dummy variables based on the sudden change points in each market.

4.2. Estimation of Univariate AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) Model with and without Sudden Change Dummies

We estimate the univariate AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) model with and without sudden change dummy variables. The results are summarized in Table 3, Table 4 and Table 5. In these tables, most estimates of ω , α and β are positive values at the 5% level of significance. The sum of parameters ( α + β ) is very high and close to one; 0.8804 for the EUA, 0.9310 for biofuel, and 0.9804 for Brent oil. This reflects the persistence of volatility, meaning that the shock could be a permanent impact on the variance of returns. However, considering the dummy variables, the sum of parameters ( α + β ) in the volatility of all three markets are 0.7228 for the EUA, 0.6714 for biofuel, and 0.3141 for Brent oil. This evidence is consistent with the studies of Aggarwal et al. [2], Hammoudeh and Li [55], Wang and Moore [56], Kang and Yoon [57] and others, whom discovered that the standard GARCH model overestimates the persistence of volatility when it ignores sudden changes in conditional variance.
In Panel B of Table 3, Table 4 and Table 5, the calculated statistics of the Ljung-Box Q test for no serial correlation of the returns and the squared returns do not reject the null hypothesis at the 5% level of significance. And the calculated statistics of the ARCH LM(5) test show that there are no remaining ARCH effects. These results determine that the AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) model illustrates the volatility of these three markets well.
On the other hand, the estimates of the sudden change dummy variables display that all dummy variables except for D 3 are significant at the 10% level in the Brent oil market. These results demonstrate that the volatility of three markets has changed significantly over time, as displayed in Figure 1 and Table 2. And the calculated log-likelihood values in all the tables are larger for the model with dummies. This finding means that the model with sudden change dummies is a better than the model without the dummies. Thus, we could continue the empirical analysis considering the sudden changes.

4.3. Estimation of Trivariate VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK Model with and without Sudden Change Dummies

To investigate the spillover effects among the EUA, biofuel and Brent oil markets, we estimate the trivariate VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK model with and without the sudden change dummies. Table 6 summarizes the results of the estimated models.
As explained later, the diagnostic test results in Panel C of Table 7 show that most of the Ljung-Box Q test results have no serial correlation and no ARCH effect remains. Therefore, in this study, it can be confirmed that the VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK model trivariate is suitable for our analysis.

4.4. Wald Test for Spillover Effects

Table 7 summarizes the Wald test results for the dynamic volatility spillover among the EUA, biofuel, and Brent oil price returns, and the diagnostic tests for the VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK model estimation results in Table 6.
Looking at the diagnostic test results in Panel C of Table 7, we can see the remaining serial correlation and the ARCH effect are weaker in the model with the sudden change dummies. And the calculated log-likelihood values are larger for the model with dummies. These results mean that the model with the sudden change dummies is a better specification than the model without them. Thus, we continue the empirical analysis considering the sudden changes, and explain the results of Wald test only for the model with the sudden change dummies.
Panel A of Table 7 summarizes the Wald test results for the existence of spillover effects among the three markets using the VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK model with the sudden change dummies. As shown in the table, the null hypothesis of no spillover effects among the three markets through the parameter α i j is rejected at the 5% level of significance, suggesting evidence of the impact of the shock on one market on the volatility in another market. However, the null hypothesis of no spillover effect among these markets through the parameter β i j is not rejected at the 10% level of significance, implying no evidence of the volatility spillover from one market to another market. The null hypothesis that there are no spillover effects among the three markets through the parameters α i j or β i j is rejected at the 10% level of significance, implying weak evidence that the spillover effects exist among three markets.
Panel B of Table 7 summarizes the results of Wald test for the existence of spillover effects between two markets. The null hypothesis of no volatility spillover effect from the EUA ( i = 1 ) to biofuel ( i = 2 ) markets is not rejected. The null hypothesis that there is no volatility spillover effect from biofuel ( i = 2 ) to the EUA ( i = 1 ) markets is not rejected, too. However, the null hypothesis of no volatility spillover effect between the EUA and biofuel markets is not rejected at the 10% level of significance, implying weak evidence of the existence of spillover effects between these two markets.
The null hypothesis of no volatility spillover effect from the EUA ( i = 1 ) to Brent oil ( i = 3 ) markets is not rejected, while the null hypothesis of no volatility spillover effect from Brent oil ( i = 3 ) to the EUA ( i = 1 ) markets is rejected at the 1% level of significance. The null hypothesis of no volatility spillover effect between the EUA and Brent oil markets is rejected at the 5% significance level, implying strong evidence of the existence of spillover effects between these two markets.
The null hypothesis of no volatility spillover effect from (to) the biofuel ( i = 2 ) to (from) Brent oil ( i = 3 ) markets is not rejected. The null hypothesis of no volatility spillover effect between the Brent oil ( i = 3 ) to biofuel ( i = 2 ) markets is also not rejected. Thus, we cannot find any evidence of volatility connectedness between the biofuel and Brent oil markets.

4.5. Calculation of Optimal Portfolio Weights and Hedge Ratios

Table 8 summarizes the optimal average weights for portfolios of two assets and the portfolio’s risk-minimized hedge ratios. Panel A of Table 8 demonstrates that for the Portfolio I consisting of the EUA and biofuel, the optimal weight for the portfolio is 0.1615, indicating that 16.15% of total asset should be invested in the EUA market, while the remaining 83.85% should be held in the biofuel market. In case of the Portfolio II consisting of the EUA and Brent oil, the optimal weight for the portfolio is 0.2918 that means 29.18% of total assets should be invested in the EUA market and the remaining 72.51% should be held in the Brent oil market. Portfolio III consisting of the biofuel and Brent oil shows the optimal weight for the asset portfolio is 0.6995, meaning that 69.95% of total asset should be invested in the biofuel market, and the remaining portion of 30.05% should be held in the Brent oil market.
Panel B of Table 8 displays the results of the risk-minimized hedge ratio. For Portfolio I, the average hedge ratio is −0.0851, which means that when an investor takes a long position (position to hold) of $1 in the EUA market, it can be effectively hedged the investment in the EUA by taking a long position of $0.0851 in the biofuel market as well. For the Portfolio II, the average hedge ratio is 0.0714, and when an investor takes a long position of $1 in the EUA market, taking a short position (position not to hold) of $0.0714 in the Brent oil market can be effectively hedged the investment in the EUA. In case of the Portfolio III, the average hedge ratio is 0.1552, implying that the biofuel investment can be effectively hedged by taking a short position of $0.1552 dollars in the Brent oil market when taking a long position of $1 in the biofuel market.
Figure 2 shows the time-varying correlations of conditional variances between two markets, which are calculated from the estimation results of the VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK model with the sudden changes. A positive (+) value of correlation means that the portfolio composed of two assets can be used for diversification. As the correlation gets closer to 1.0, indicating that two assets respond equally to market changes, thus the diversification ability of asset composition is diminished. On the other hand, a negative (−) value of correlation indicates that a portfolio of two assets is a means for hedging market changes. When the correlation approaches −1.0, both assets can be treated as the other’s safe haven assets. Figure 2a,b suggest the possibility that the EUA acts as a hedging for the energy source markets. This possibility is more pronounced between the EUA and biofuel markets, with at least four sharply low correlations. On the other hand, the diversification ability of assets is stronger between the biofuel and Brent oil markets, with positive correlations in most sample periods.

5. Conclusions

In recent years, there has been a growing interest in the market price interactions between carbon (or clean/renewable energy) and traditional fossil energy sources such as coal and oil. The relationship between the two markets provides the necessary information for the industrial sector to plan the transition of energy consumption structures and to formulate their optimal carbon emission strategies. On the other hand, this is also important information in determining an asset portfolio in financial markets.
The purpose of this study is to investigate these issues, for the weekly data of the EUA futures, biofuel and Brent oil prices from 25 October 2009 to 5 July 2020. We employed the vector autoregressive-generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (VAR-GARCH) model with the Baba, Engle, Kraft and Krone (BEKK) specification [58]. Our results may be summarized as follows:
  • First, we identified the sudden changes and the volatility persistence in the three markets, and also confirmed that the volatility of the markets has changed significantly over time. In detail, during the sample period, the EUA, biofuel, and Brent oil markets had 3, 1, and 4 sudden change points, respectively. These time points of change can be explained by many factors, but major events such as the recession after the global financial crisis happened in 2008, the imbalance of supply and demand with the structural changes in the global oil market, and the unprecedented global economic stiffness caused by the COVID-19 pandemic would have affected.
  • Second, we found a weak volatility spillover effect among the three markets, and a strong spillover effect between the EUA and Brent oil markets. In particular, the effect of volatility spillover from the Brent oil market to the EUA market was stronger than the opposite case. This means that if the volatility of Brent oil price changes increases due to the inconsistency between oil supply and demand in the market, it can have a significant effect on the EUA price changes, accordingly. On the other hand, we could not find any evidence of volatility spillover between the biofuel and Brent oil markets.
  • Lastly, in financial markets, the EUA as an asset can be used as a hedging portfolio for energy sources. In other words, by holding the EUA and the energy sources together as assets, investors can effectively hedge their risk of investment. The possibility of hedging is more pronounced between the EUA and biofuel markets, while the diversification ability of assets is stronger between the biofuel and Brent oil markets. This means that trying to hold both the biofuel and Brent oil assets at the same time is not an appropriate action for investors to minimize the risk of investment.
As Jackson and Robertson [59] argued, using carbon trading to change the behaviour of government and industrial sectors is more likely to have a more immediate influence on carbon emissions than encouraging individuals to purchase low-carbon products and services. And, as many experts say, the carbon market will play an increasingly substantial role than now in effectively reducing global carbon emissions.
Furthermore, our results suggest that carbon trading can be an attractive investment asset in the financial market as well. In short, a well-structured portfolio considering carbon as an asset in the financial market can help investors manage their investment risk. These results also mean that there is an incentive for energy-intensive facilities such as power generation plants, industrial plants, and airlines to cost-effectively participate in the carbon market.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Y.L. and S.-M.Y.; methodology, Y.L.; software, Y.L.; validation, Y.L. and S.-M.Y.; formal analysis, Y.L.; investigation, Y.L. and S.-M.Y.; resources, S.-M.Y.; data curation, S.-M.Y.; writing—original draft preparation, Y.L. and S.-M.Y.; writing—review and editing, S.-M.Y.; visualization, Y.L.; supervision, S.-M.Y.; project administration, S.-M.Y.; funding acquisition, S.-M.Y. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported by the Ministry of Education of the Korea and the National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF-2017S1A5B8057488).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Subramaniam, N.; Wahyuni, D.; Cooper, B.J.; Leung, P.; Wines, G. Integration of carbon risks and opportunities in enterprise risk management systems: Evidence from Australian firms. J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 96, 407–417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Zhang, Y.-J.; Wei, Y.-M. Interpreting the complex impact of fossil fuel markets on the EU ETS futures markets: An empirical evidence. Manag. Rev. 2010, 21, 34–41. [Google Scholar]
  3. Fikru, M.G.; Gautier, L. The impact of weather variation on energy consumption in residential houses. Appl. Energy 2015, 144, 19–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Liu, H.-H.; Chen, Y.-C. A study on the volatility spillovers, long memory effects and interactions between carbon and energy markets: The impacts of extreme weather. Econ. Model. 2013, 35, 840–855. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Chiarini, A. Strategies for developing an environmentally sustainable supply chain: Differences between manufacturing and service sectors. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2013, 23, 493–504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Yunus, S.; Elijido-Ten, E.; Abhayawansa, S. Determinants of carbon management strategy adoption. Manag. Audit. J. 2016, 31, 156–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Alsaifi, K.; Elnahass, M.; Salama, A. Market responses to firms’ voluntary carbon disclosure: Empirical evidence from the United Kingdom. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 262, 121377. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Gallego-Álvarez, I.; Segura, L.; Martínez-Ferrero, J. Carbon emission reduction: The impact on the financial and operational performance of international companies. J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 103, 149–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Aatola, P.; Ollikainen, M.; Toppinen, A. Price determination in the EU ETS market: Theory and econometric analysis with market fundamentals. Energy Econ. 2013, 36, 380–395. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Chevallier, J. Evaluating the carbon-macroeconomy relationship: Evidence from threshold vector error-correction and Markov-switching VAR models. Econ. Model. 2011, 28, 2634–2656. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Keppler, J.H.; Mansanet-Bataller, M. Causalities between CO2, electricity, and other energy variables during phase I and phase II of the EU ETS. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 3329–3341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Nazifi, F.; Milunovich, G. Measuring the impact of carbon allowance trading on energy prices. Energy Environ. 2010, 21, 367–383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. International Energy Agency (IEA). World Energy Outlook 2015; International Energy Agency: Paris, France, 2015; Available online: https://www.iea.org/reports/world-energy-outlook-2015 (accessed on 25 July 2020).
  14. Chevallier, J. A model of carbon price interactions with macroeconomic and energy dynamics. Energy Econ. 2011, 33, 1295–1312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Balcılar, M.; Demirer, R.; Hammoudeh, S.; Nguyen, D.K. Risk spillovers across the energy and carbon markets and hedging strategies for carbon risk. Energy Econ. 2016, 54, 159–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Ortas, E.; Álvarez, I. The efficacy of the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Depicting the co-movement of carbon assets and energy commodities through wavelet decomposition. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 116, 40–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Zhang, Y.-J.; Sun, Y.-F. The dynamic volatility spillover between European carbon trading market and fossil energy market. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 112, 2654–2663. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Dhamija, A.K.; Yadav, S.S.; Jain, P.K. Volatility spillover of energy markets into EUA markets under EU ETS: A multi-phase study. Environ. Econ. Policy Stud. 2018, 20, 561–591. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Ji, Q.; Zhang, D.; Geng, J. Information linkage, dynamic spillovers in prices and volatility between the carbon and energy markets. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 198, 972–978. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Uddin, G.S.; Areola Hernandez, J.; Shahzad, S.J.H.; Hedström, A. Multivariate dependence and spillover effects across energy commodities and diversification potentials of carbon assets. Energy Econ. 2018, 71, 35–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Chevallier, J.; Nguyen, D.K.; Reboredo, J.C. A conditional dependence approach to CO2-energy price relationships. Energy Econ. 2019, 81, 812–821. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Wu, Q.; Wang, M.; Tian, L. The market-linkage of the volatility spillover between traditional energy price and carbon price on the realization of carbon value of emission reduction behavior. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 245, 118682. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Castagneto-Gissey, G. How competitive are EU electricity markets? An assessment of ETS Phase II. Energy Policy 2014, 73, 278–297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Hammoudeh, S.; Nguyen, D.K.; Sousa, R.M. What explain the short-term dynamics of the prices of CO2 emissions? Energy Econ. 2014, 46, 122–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Hammoudeh, S.; Lahiani, A.; Khuong, D.K.; Sousa, R.M. An empirical analysis of energy cost pass-through to CO2 emission prices. Energy Econ. 2015, 49, 149–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Fezzi, C.; Bunn, D.W. Structural interactions of European carbon trading and energy prices. J. Energy Mark. 2019, 2, 53–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Hammoudeh, S.; Nguyen, D.K.; Sousa, R.M. Energy prices and CO2 emission allowance prices: A quantile regression approach. Energy Policy 2014, 70, 201–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. USDA Foreign Agriculture Service (USDA-FAS). EU Biofuels Annual 2012; USDA Foreign Agriculture Service: Washington, DC, USA, 2012. Available online: https://apps.fas.usda.gov/newgainapi/api/report/downloadreportbyfilename?filename=Biofuels%20Annual_The%20Hague_EU-27_6-25-2012.pdf (accessed on 25 July 2020).
  29. Ajanovic, A.; Haas, R. On the future prospects and limits of biofuels in Brazil, the US and EU. Appl. Energy 2014, 135, 730–737. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Reboredo, J.C. Volatility spillovers between the oil market and the European Union carbon emission market. Econ. Model. 2014, 36, 229–234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Wise, M.; Dooley, J.; Luckow, P.; Calvin, K.; Kyle, P. Agriculture, land use, energy and carbon emission impacts of global biofuel mandates to mid-century. Appl. Energy 2014, 114, 763–773. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Chiu, F.-P.; Hsu, C.-S.; Ho, A.; Chen, C.-C. Modeling the price relationships between crude oil, energy crops and biofuels. Energy 2016, 109, 845–857. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Chao, H.; Agusdinata, D.B.; DeLaurentis, D.A. The potential impacts of Emissions Trading Scheme and biofuel options to carbon emissions of U.S. airlines. Energy Policy 2019, 134, 110993. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Chen, Y.; Qu, F.; Li, W.; Chen, M. Volatility spillover and dynamic correlation between the carbon market and energy markets. J. Bus. Econ. Manag. 2019, 20, 979–999. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Crago, C.L.; Khanna, M. Carbon abatement in the fuel market with biofuels: Implications for second best policies. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2014, 67, 89–103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  36. Reboredo, J.C.; Rivera-Castro, M.A.; Ugolini, A. Wavelet-based test of co-movement and causality between oil and renewable energy stock prices. Energy Econ. 2017, 61, 241–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Sadorsky, P. Modeling renewable energy company risk. Energy Policy 2012, 40, 39–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Dutta, A. Cointegration and nonlinear causality among ethanol-related prices: Evidence from Brazil. GCB Bioenergy 2018, 10, 335–342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Dutta, A. Impact of carbon emission trading on the European Union biodiesel feedstock market. Biomass Bioenergy 2019, 128, 105328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Chang, T.-H.; Su, H.-M. The substitutive effect of biofuels on fossil fuels in the lower and higher crude oil price periods. Energy 2010, 35, 2807–2813. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Serra, T.; Zilberman, D.; Gil, J.M. Price volatility in ethanol markets. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 2011, 38, 259–280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  42. Serra, T.; Zilberman, D.; Gil, J.M.; Goodwin, B.K. Nonlinearities in the U.S. corn-ethanol-oil-gasoline price system. Agric. Econ. 2011, 42, 35–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Hossain, A.K.M.N.; Serletis, A. Biofuel substitution in the U.S. transportation sector. J. Econ. Asymmetries 2020, 22, e00161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Miralles-Marcelo, J.L.; Miralles-Quirós, J.L.; del Mar Miralles-Quirós, M. Multivariate GARCH models and risk minimizing portfolios: The importance of medium and small firms. Span. Rev. Financ. Econ. 2013, 11, 29–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Jiao, X.; Jiang, Z.; Yoon, S.-M. Volatility spillover effects and the risk minimizing portfolios in Chinese stock markets. J. Ind. Econ. Bus. 2015, 28, 2381–2407. (In Korean) [Google Scholar]
  46. Engle, R.F. Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance of United Kingdom inflation. Econometrica 1982, 50, 987–1007. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Elliott, G.; Rothenberg, T.J.; Stock, J.H. Efficient tests for an autoregressive unit root. Econometrica 1996, 64, 813–836. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  48. Phillips, P.C.B.; Perron, P. Testing for a unit root in time series regression. Biometrica 1988, 75, 335–346. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Kwiatkowski, D.; Phillips, P.C.B.; Schmidt, P.; Shin, Y. Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root: How sure are we that economic time series have a unit root? J. Econ. 1992, 54, 159–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Bollerslev, T. Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity. J. Econ. 1986, 31, 307–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  51. Inclán, C.; Tiao, G.C. Use of cumulative sums of squares for retrospective detection of changes of variance. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 1994, 89, 913–923. [Google Scholar]
  52. Aggarwal, R.; Inclan, C.; Leal, R. Volatility in emerging stock markets. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 1999, 34, 33–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Kroner, K.F.; Ng, V.K. Modeling asymmetric co-movements of asset returns. Rev. Financ. Stud. 1998, 11, 817–844. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Kroner, K.F.; Sultan, J. Time-varying distributions and dynamic hedging with foreign currency futures. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 1993, 28, 535–551. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Hammoudeh, S.; Li, H. Sudden changes in volatility in emerging markets: The case of Gulf Arab stock markets. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 2008, 17, 47–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Wang, P.; Moore, T. Sudden changes in volatility: The case of five central European stock markets. J. Int. Financ. Mark. Inst. Money 2009, 19, 33–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  57. Kang, S.H.; Yoon, S.-M. The impact of sudden changes on volatility persistence and information transmission in Chinese stock markets. J. Econ. Stud. 2013, 31, 177–199. [Google Scholar]
  58. Baba, Y.; Engle, R.F.; Kraft, D.F.; Kroner, K.F. Multivariate Simultaneous Generalized ARCH; Department of Economics, University of California: San Diego, CA, USA, 1991; Unpublished manuscript. [Google Scholar]
  59. Jackson, F.; Robertson, D. Is the Idea of Carbon Trading Just a Lot of Hot Air? The Times. 5 November 2009. Available online: https://www.thetimes.co.uk/article/is-the-idea-of-carbon-trading-just-a-lot-of-hot-air-smrnzn0njmb (accessed on 25 July 2020).
Figure 1. Price dynamics and sudden changes in returns dynamics (Note: The dotted lines define the band of ±3 standard deviations around the points of sudden changes estimated by the iterative cumulative sum of squares (ICSS) algorithm): (a) the EUA price; (b) the EUA returns; (c) biofuel price; (d) biofuel returns; (e) Brent oil price; (f) Brent oil returns.
Figure 1. Price dynamics and sudden changes in returns dynamics (Note: The dotted lines define the band of ±3 standard deviations around the points of sudden changes estimated by the iterative cumulative sum of squares (ICSS) algorithm): (a) the EUA price; (b) the EUA returns; (c) biofuel price; (d) biofuel returns; (e) Brent oil price; (f) Brent oil returns.
Energies 13 04382 g001
Figure 2. Time-varying correlations between two volatilities. Note: The correlations between two conditional variances are calculated from the estimates of the VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK model with the sudden changes: (a) the EUA-biofuel; (b) the EUA-Brent oil; (c) biofuel-Brent oil.
Figure 2. Time-varying correlations between two volatilities. Note: The correlations between two conditional variances are calculated from the estimates of the VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK model with the sudden changes: (a) the EUA-biofuel; (b) the EUA-Brent oil; (c) biofuel-Brent oil.
Energies 13 04382 g002
Table 1. Descriptive statistics and unit root test results for the returns.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics and unit root test results for the returns.
Statistic/TestEUABiofuelBrent Oil
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics
Mean0.1262−0.0661−0.1062
Maximum24.554510.854919.9191
Minimum−38.7855−10.9349−24.5892
Standard deviation6.67862.72344.4348
Skewness−0.75550.1105−0.7467
Kurtosis7.67574.04557.8141
Jarque-Bera557.36 ***26.3561 ***586.48 ***
Q ( 20 ) 28.420 *29.671 *55.367 ***
Q s ( 20 ) 26.957154.753 ***368.356 ***
ARCH LM(5)13.357 **76.757 ***133.313 ***
Panel B: Results of Unit Root Tests
DF-GLS−22.0290 ***−4.5310 ***−4.8328 ***
PP−22.5897 ***−21.7536 ***−20.6669 ***
KPSS0.30050.07950.1068
Notes: Jarque-Bera refers to the test statistic calculated for the null hypothesis of normality. Q ( 20 ) and Q s ( 20 ) refer to the Ljung-Box test statistics for the null hypothesis that there is no serial correlation of returns and squared returns, respectively. The ARCH LM(5) test of Engle [46] checks the presence of the ARCH effect. The DF-GLS, PP, and KPSS are the test statistics of the augmented GLS-detrended Dickey-Fuller test [47], the Phillips-Perron unit root test [48], and the Kwiatkowski et al. stationarity test [49], respectively. *** (**, *) represents the rejection of the null hypotheses at the 1% (5%, 10%) level of significance.
Table 2. Sudden change points identified by the ICSS algorithm and standard deviations.
Table 2. Sudden change points identified by the ICSS algorithm and standard deviations.
Number of Sudden ChangesSub-PeriodsStandard Deviations
EUA325 Oct. 2009–28 Oct. 20125.8251
4 Nov. 2012–30 Mar. 20149.7364
6 Apr. 2014–29 May. 20164.2217
5 Jun. 2016–5 Jul. 20207.0095
Biofuel125 Oct. 2009–22 Jul. 20123.8174
29 Jul. 2012–5 Jul. 20202.2359
Brent oil425 Oct. 2009–15 Jul. 20123.7895
22 Jul. 2012–16 Nov. 20142.1977
23 Nov. 2014–27 Nov. 20165.2373
04 Dec. 2016–16 Feb. 20203.7198
23 Feb. 2020–5 Jul. 202012.7009
Table 3. Estimation results of AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) model for the EUA returns.
Table 3. Estimation results of AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) model for the EUA returns.
Without the Sudden Change DummiesWith the Sudden Change Dummies
Panel A: Estimates of the Univariate AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) Model
μ 0.3483 (0.2726)0.2649 (0.2327)
EUA returns (−1)0.0312 (0.0511)0.0237 (0.0523)
ω 5.8671 (2.0541) ***9.6061 (3.1836) ***
α 0.1464 (0.0508) ***0.0987 (0.0410) **
β 0.7340 (0.0758) ***0.6241 (0.0987) ***
D 1 -19.9769 (8.4173) **
D 2 -−5.6132 (2.2815) **
D 3 -4.3918 (2.6537) *
( α + β ) 0.88040.7228
Panel B: Results of Diagnostic Tests
Log likelihood−1816.0342−1791.9016
Q ( 20 ) 17.810 [0.5999]18.606 [0.5476]
Q s ( 20 ) 7.827 [0.9930]9.316 [0.9790]
ARCH LM(5)0.407 [0.8440]0.376 [0.8653]
Notes: The standard errors are in parentheses and the p -values are in brackets. See also the note of Table 1.
Table 4. Estimation results of AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) model for the Biofuel returns.
Table 4. Estimation results of AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) model for the Biofuel returns.
Without the Sudden Change DummiesWith the Sudden Change Dummies
Panel A: Estimates of the Univariate AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) Model
μ −0.1367 (0.1036)−0.1343 (0.0982)
Biofuel returns (−1)0.0278 (0.0459)0.0148 (0.0471)
ω 0.5374 (0.2484) **5.0659 (2.4414) **
α 0.1645 (0.0464) ***0.1647 (0.0625) ***
β 0.7666 (0.0665) ***0.5067 (0.1703) ***
D 1 -−3.4303 (1.8198) *
( α + β ) 0.93100.6714
Panel B: Results of Diagnostic Tests
Log likelihood−1304.3633−1295.2755
Q ( 20 ) 20.871 [0.4048]19.152 [0.5119]
Q s ( 20 ) 19.195 [0.5092]16.295 [0.6982]
ARCH LM(5)0.620 [0.6846]0.478 [0.7926]
Note: See the notes of Table 1 and Table 3.
Table 5. Estimation results of AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) model for the Brent oil returns.
Table 5. Estimation results of AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) model for the Brent oil returns.
Without the Sudden Change DummiesWith the Sudden Change Dummies
Panel A: Estimates of the Univariate AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) Model
μ −0.0344 (0.1489)−0.0975 (0.1380)
Brent oil returns (−1)0.0292 (0.0485)0.0386 (0.0414)
ω 0.5448 (0.3659)9.9955 (3.1183) ***
α 0.1321 (0.0303) ***−0.0338 (0.0335)
β 0.8483 (0.0409) ***0.3480 (0.1890) *
D 1 -−6.8351 (2.2935) ***
D 2 -9.6980 (3.9109) **
D 3 -−0.9368 (1.1755)
D 4 -95.0835 (39.631) **
( α + β ) 0.98040.3141
Panel B: Results of Diagnostic Tests
Log likelihood−1538.0533−1506.1258
Q ( 20 ) 29.697 [0.0749] *22.090 [0.3357]
Q s ( 20 ) 18.822 [0.5334]27.305 [0.1269]
ARCH LM(5)1.043 [0.3913]1.538 [0.1760]
Note: See the notes of Table 1 and Table 3.
Table 6. Estimation results of VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK model for the EUA, biofuel, and Brent oil returns.
Table 6. Estimation results of VAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)-BEKK model for the EUA, biofuel, and Brent oil returns.
ParametersWithout the Sudden Change DummiesWith the Sudden Change Dummies
c 1 0.1642(0.2972)0.1868(0.3071)
a 11 −0.0090(0.0473)0.0059(0.0568)
a 12 0.0492(0.0835)−0.0375(0.1285)
a 13 0.0233(0.0648)0.0091(0.0805)
c 2 −0.1737(0.1049) *−0.0474(0.1117)
a 21 0.0067(0.0158)0.0026(0.0188)
a 22 0.0479(0.0396)0.0495(0.0481)
a 23 0.0284(0.0234)0.0172(0.0327)
c 3 −0.0304(0.1442)−0.1455(0.1611)
a 31 0.0476(0.0212) **0.0516(0.0251) **
a 32 0.0895(0.0557)0.0891(0.0685)
a 33 −0.0018(0.0398)0.0286(0.0531)
c 11 2.0149(0.4091) ***1.5111(2.9682)
c 21 0.1339(0.1636)−2.7690(1.7051)
c 22 0.4283(0.1387) ***0.2753(5.2922)
c 31 −0.0901(0.2432)2.6341(7.5780)
c 32 −0.7814(0.1919) ***4.5095(5.0844)
c 33 0.0005(0.8264)0.1415(0.3039)
α 11 0.2444(0.0540) ***0.1614(0.0788) **
α 12 −0.0188(0.0155)−0.0646(0.0368) *
α 13 −0.0447(0.0210) **−0.0445(0.0511)
α 21 0.0315(0.1172)0.2964(0.1421) **
α 22 0.2177(0.0463) ***0.2230(0.1037) **
α 23 −0.1078(0.0571) *−0.0564(0.1302)
α 31 0.1175(0.0742)−0.2272(0.1102) **
α 32 −0.0402(0.0227) *−0.0520(0.0624)
α 33 0.3805(0.0408) ***0.1701(0.0950) *
β 11 0.9195(0.0295) ***0.8340(0.1025) ***
β 12 0.0026(0.0085)−0.0586(0.0646)
β 13 0.0254(0.0137) *−0.0343(0.0675)
β 21 −0.0098(0.0542)−0.3679(0.4717)
β 22 0.9466(0.0197) ***0.5428(0.2611) **
β 23 0.0522(0.0276) *−0.0391(0.3882)
β 31 −0.0569(0.0386)−0.1792(0.1376)
β 32 0.0353(0.0127) ***−0.1936(0.1069) *
β 33 0.9040(0.0196) ***0.5897(0.1749) ***
Notes: Figures in the parentheses are the standard errors of the estimates. *** (**, *) represents the rejection of the null hypotheses at the 1% (5%, 10%) level of significance. The estimates of sudden change dummies are not reported to save space.
Table 7. Wald test for dynamic volatility spillover among the EUA, Biofuel, and Brent oil returns.
Table 7. Wald test for dynamic volatility spillover among the EUA, Biofuel, and Brent oil returns.
Hypothesis/Test StatisticWithout Sudden Change DummiesWith Sudden Change Dummies
Panel A: Wald test results for volatility spillover among three markets
H 0 :   i = 1 3 j = 1 ( i j ) 3 α i j = 0 23.0030 [0.0008] ***13.0519 [0.0422] **
H 0 :   i = 1 3 j = 1 ( i j ) 3 β i j = 0 32.6676 [0.0000] ***5.4815 [0.4837]
H 0 :   i = 1 3 j = 1 ( i j ) 3 α i j = 0 and i = 1 3 j = 1 ( i j ) 3 β i j = 0 41.3946 [0.0000] ***20.0821 [0.0655] *
Panel B: Wald test results for volatility spillover between two markets
H 0 :   α 12 = β 12 = 0 1.9516 [0.3769]4.5675 [0.1019]
H 0 :   α 21 = β 21 = 0 0.0735 [0.9639]4.3540 [0.1134]
H 0 :   α 12 = β 12 = α 21 = β 21 = 0 2.0675 [0.7233]8.9997 [0.0611] *
H 0 :   α 13 = β 13 = 0 4.8350 [0.0891] *1.0547 [0.5902]
H 0 :   α 31 = β 31 = 0 2.6440 [0.2666]9.6522 [0.0080] ***
H 0 :   α 13 = β 13 = α 31 = β 31 = 0 6.0848 [0.1929]10.1175 [0.0385] **
H 0 :   α 23 = β 23 = 0 4.4584 [0.1076]0.2488 [0.8830]
H 0 :   α 32 = β 32 = 0 8.1173 [0.0173] **4.5436 [0.1031]
H 0 :   α 23 = β 23 = α 32 = β 32 = 0 17.1020 [0.0018] ***4.8128 [0.3071]
Panel C: Diagnostic test results
Log-likelihood−4640.2370−4568.0657
Q ( 20 ) , EUA equation18.5913 [0.5485]17.7176 [0.6157]
Q ( 20 ) , Biofuel equation20.6701 [0.4168]21.1804 [0.6060]
Q ( 20 ) , Brent oil equation30.6007 [0.0607] *31.8136 [0.3866]
Q s ( 20 ) , EUA equation7.7760 [0.9933]10.5892 [0.1091]
Q s ( 20 ) , Biofuel equation42.9214 [0.0021] ***31.3813 [0.9562]
Q s ( 20 ) , Brent oil equation17.1160 [0.6454]22.6207 [0.0504] *
ARCH LM(5), EUA equation2.00 [0.8491]2.51 [0.7749]
ARCH LM(5), Biofuel equation24.32 [0.0002] ***11.41 [0.0438] **
ARCH LM(5), Brent oil equation5.46 [0.3626]7.57 [0.1816]
Notes: The subscript 1 (2, 3) denotes the EUA (biofuel, Brent oil) market. α i j represents the impact of shock on the i market on the volatility in the j market. β i j represents the degree of volatility spillover effect from the i market to the j market. Figures in Panel A and B are χ 2 statistics for the Wald test. The p -values are in brackets. *** (**, *) represents the rejection of the null hypotheses at the 1% (5%, 10%) level of significance.
Table 8. Optimal portfolio weights and hedge ratios for the EUA, biofuel and Brent oil markets using the model with the sudden change dummies.
Table 8. Optimal portfolio weights and hedge ratios for the EUA, biofuel and Brent oil markets using the model with the sudden change dummies.
AssetPortfolio I
(EUA-Biofuel)
Portfolio II
(EUA-Brent Oil)
Portfolio III
(Biofuel-Brent Oil)
Panel A: Average of optimal portfolio weights
EUA0.16150.2918
Biofuel0.83850.6995
Brent oil0.70820.3005
Panel B: Risk-minimized hedge ratios
Mean−0.08510.07140.1552
Median−0.02470.09640.1185
Maximum0.81470.81350.7895
Minimum−1.6765−1.3177−0.1024
Notes: The Portfolio I, II, and III are composed of the EUA and biofuel, the EUA and Brent oil, and the biofuel and Brent oil assets, respectively.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Lee, Y.; Yoon, S.-M. Dynamic Spillover and Hedging among Carbon, Biofuel and Oil. Energies 2020, 13, 4382. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/en13174382

AMA Style

Lee Y, Yoon S-M. Dynamic Spillover and Hedging among Carbon, Biofuel and Oil. Energies. 2020; 13(17):4382. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/en13174382

Chicago/Turabian Style

Lee, Yeonjeong, and Seong-Min Yoon. 2020. "Dynamic Spillover and Hedging among Carbon, Biofuel and Oil" Energies 13, no. 17: 4382. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/en13174382

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop